Skip to main content

ORIGINAL RESEARCH article

Front. Public Health, 05 March 2021
Sec. Infectious Diseases – Surveillance, Prevention and Treatment
This article is part of the Research Topic COVID-19: Integrating Artificial Intelligence, Data Science, Mathematics, Medicine and Public Health, Epidemiology, Neuroscience, and Biomedical Science in Pandemic Management View all 95 articles

Analysis of the Tradeoff Between Health and Economic Impacts of the Covid-19 Epidemic

\nSamson LasaulceSamson Lasaulce1Chao Zhang
Chao Zhang2*Vineeth VarmaVineeth Varma1Irinel Constantin Mor&#x;rescuIrinel Constantin Morărescu1
  • 1Université de Lorraine, CNRS, CRAN, Nancy, France
  • 2School of Mathematics and Statistics, Central South University, Changsha, China

Various measures have been taken in different countries to mitigate the Covid-19 epidemic. But, throughout the world, many citizens don't understand well how these measures are taken and even question the decisions taken by their government. Should the measures be more (or less) restrictive? Are they taken for a too long (or too short) period of time? To provide some quantitative elements of response to these questions, we consider the well-known SEIR model for the Covid-19 epidemic propagation and propose a pragmatic model of the government decision-making operation. Although simple and obviously improvable, the proposed model allows us to study the tradeoff between health and economic aspects in a pragmatic and insightful way. Assuming a given number of phases for the epidemic (namely, 4 in this paper) and a desired tradeoff between health and economic aspects, it is then possible to determine the optimal duration of each phase and the optimal severity level (i.e., the target transmission rate) for each of them. The numerical analysis is performed for the case of France but the adopted approach can be applied to any country. One of the takeaway messages of this analysis is that being able to implement the optimal 4−phase epidemic management strategy in France would have led to 1.05 million of infected people and a GDP loss of 231 billions € instead of 6.88 millions of infected and a loss of 241 billions €. This indicates that, seen from the proposed model perspective, the effectively implemented epidemic management strategy is good economically, whereas substantial improvements might have been obtained in terms of health impact. Our analysis indicates that the lockdown/severe phase should have been more severe but shorter, and the adjustment phase occurred earlier. Due to the natural tendency of people to deviate from the official rules, updating measures every month over the whole epidemic episode seems to be more appropriate.

1. Introduction

One of the goals of this work is to provide a simple but exploitable model to measure the quality of the epidemic management strategy implemented by a government to mitigate the health and macro-economic impacts of the Covid-19 epidemic. The quality is measured in terms of the tradeoff between the total number of infected people over a given period of time and the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) loss, under a constraint of the total number of infected people requiring Intensive Care Units (ICU). To reach this objective, we propose a behavioral model for governmental decision-making operations. Although we assume a simple measure for the quality of the lockdown measures and a simple dynamical model (namely, a classical susceptible-exposed-infected-removed (SEIR) model), the proposed approach is seen to be sufficient to constitute a first step into capturing and quantifying the tradeoff under consideration. In contrast with most studies conducted on the Covid-19 epidemic analysis where the primary goal is to refine the SEIR model [see e.g., (15)] or employ the SEIR model by accounting for local variations [by using a given SEIR model per geographical region—see e.g., (6)] or for the impact of class type [by age, sex, risk level—see e.g., (7)] our approach is to use the standard SEIR model for an entire country and choose a simple economic model to focus on the study of the tradeoff between health and economic aspects.

Although there have been many several interesting studies on the economic impact of Covid-19 [see e.g., (812)], the pursued goal of these studies is not to model the behavior of the government. As a consequence, the proposed tradeoff has not been analyzed, at least formally. In fact, the closest contribution to this direction would be given by (13) where generic discrete-time epidemics over multiple regions are considered, the particular 4-phase structure is not considered, the focus is not on Covid-19, and the key aspect of the tradeoff analysis is neither developed nor analyzed. Additionally, the numerous studies available on the problem of the transmission rate control generally concern the continuous-time control approach. In this work, the focus is on a multiple phase approach (namely, 4 phases). In the literature dedicated to epidemic control, one can for instance find that some recent studies on how the lockdown strategies and quarantine can be planned in an optimal fashion (1417). A common feature to all these works on optimal control and lockdown planning is that the policies under consideration, vary over time in a continuous manner, i.e., the lockdown policy is continuously evolving based on the infected population or just on time. However, from the perspective of a government, implementing such policies is not practical since daily changes of the epidemic control measures are difficult to be implemented and to be followed by people.

Summarizing, compared to the existing literature on epidemics modeling and control of epidemics, the main contribution of our work is four-fold:

• A model for capturing the tradeoff between health and economic aspect and therefore for the government decision-making operation is proposed and studied;

• The focus is on multiple phase control policies and not on general continuous-time control policies (to be precise, 4 phases are assumed, see Figure 1);

• The problem of finding the optimal features of the optimal epidemic management policy (i.e., the target severity level for each phase and the switching time instants) is stated and solved exhaustively. Additionally, to refine the analysis, we assume a simple model for the natural time drift in terms of behavior of people;

• The numerical analysis of the tradeoff is dedicated to the Covid-19 epidemic and a case study for France.

FIGURE 1
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 1. One of the goals of this work is to determine numerically, for a given tradeoff between health and economic costs, the best 4−phase epidemic management policy that is, the best values for τ0, τ1, τ2, R1, R2, R3 (the epidemic time horizon T and the natural reproduction number R0 being fixed).

2. Methods

2.1. Epidemic Model

To model the dynamics of the Covid-19 epidemic globally i.e., over an entire country, we assume a standard SEIR model. Let us, respectively, denote by s, e, i, and r the fractions of the population: being susceptible to be infected by the SARS-Cov2 virus, having been exposed to it, being infected, and being removed (including recoveries and deceases). The epidemic is assumed to obey the following continuous-time dynamics:

{           dsdt(t)=-β(t)i(t)s(t)           dedt(t)=β(t)i(t)s(t)-γe(t)           didt(t)=γe(t)-δi(t)           drdt(t)=δi(t)s(t)+e(t)+i(t)+r(t)=1    (1)

where:

• β(t), t ∈ ℝ, represents the time-varying virus transmission rate;

• γ denotes the rate at which the exposed subject develops the disease (this includes people presenting symptoms and asymptomatics). The period 1γ is called the incubation period;

• δ denotes the removal rate and 1δ is called the average recovery period.

We assume that the control action u(t) taken by the decision-maker (the government or possibly a more local decision-maker) has a linear effect on the transmission virus rate. Additionally, the effectiveness of this action is assumed to undergo a non-controllable drift or attenuation effect due to the observed fact that people tend to relax their effort over time (18, 19), hence the presence of the attenuation factor a(t) yields:

β(t)=R0δ-u(t)a(t)    (2)

where R0 is the natural reproduction number (namely, without any control or population awareness), u(t) ∈ [0, U] is the control action or severity level of the lockdown measures. Note that U corresponds to the most drastic or severe control action (in theory it could reach the value R0δ and make the reproduction number vanishing). In this work, u(t) is a piecewise-constant function. For the numerical analysis, we will assume a(t) to be a linearly decreasing function of time (as detailed in the next section). Therefore, one can define the time-varying effective reproduction number:

R(t)=β(t)δ=R0-u(t)a(t)δ.    (3)

As illustrated by Figure 1, we are solving an epidemic control problem in which determining the function u(t) or R(t) amounts to jointly determining the switching instants τ0, τ12 and the targeted reproduction numbers R1, R2, R3; T is a given period of time for the epidemic analysis. In particular, we will determine the best duration of the lockdown phase τ1 and the corresponding targeted reproduction number R1. Figure 1 shows for instance that if the lockdown measures taken are such the reproduction number is R1 at the beginning of the lockdown phase, then, because of the drift induced by the typical human behavior, the effective reproduction number increases over time.

2.2. Time Drift or People Behavior Model

We propose here a model for the attenuation function a(t), which quantifies the degree to which people relax their effort to implement the government management measures. As the attenuation effect is negligible when a new policy is released, we consider that a(t) = 1 when t ∈ {τ0, τ1, τ2}. The attenuation factor is assumed to increase over time in each phase, and we assume the following piecewise linear behavior between phases:

a(t)={1for t<τ0,1-a1(t-τ0)for τ0t<τ1,1-a2(t-τ1)for τ1t<τ2,1-a3(t-τ2)for tτ2.    (4)

where a1, a2, and a3, respectively, represent the attenuation coefficients during the lockdown phase, after the lockdown phase, and during the adjustment phase.

2.3. Decision-Maker Behavior Model

The proposed model for the behavior of the decision-maker is based on the fact that it wants to obtain a given tradeoff between economic and health aspects. For the cost related to the economics loss, we assume the simplest reasonable model. That is, we assume that economic cost is quadratic in the control action. For the health cost, we assume that it is given by the number of infected people over the given period of time. Therefore, the proposed overall cost consists of a convex combination of these two costs. By minimizing the overall cost, one realizes the desired tradeoff between economic and health aspects. On top of this we impose the number of patients requiring intensive care to be under a given threshold NmaxICU. Thus, the corresponding minimization is performed under a constraint on the number of people infected at any time t ∈ [0, T]: σNi(t)NmaxICU, N being the population size, NmaxICU the maximum number of ICU patients, and 0 ≤ σ ≤ 1 is the percentage of infected people requiring intensive care. In France, official records state that the maximum cumulated number of ICU patients has reached 7, 148 (on April 8, 2020) but the capacity over the whole territory has been evaluated to be greater than 15, 000. By denoting α ∈ [0, 1] the weight assigned to the macroeconomic impact of the epidemic and Ke > 0, Kh > 0, μ > 0 some constants (parameters) defined below, obtaining the desired tradeoff amounts to finding a solution of the following optimization problem (OP) while fixing α to a given value:

minimize u(t){αKe{0τ0+τ1u2(t)dt+1μ12τ0+τ1τ0+τ1+τ2                   u2(t)dt+1μ22τ0+τ1+τ2Tu2(t)dt}+(1-α)Kh[s(0)-s(T)]}subject to  t[0,T], σNi(t)NmaxICU                      τ1Tmin                      Equations (1) and (2)    (5)

where:

Ke > 0 and Kh > 0 are constants that weight the economic and health cost functions (they also act as conversion factors allowing one to obtain appropriate units and orders of magnitude);

• τ0 and τ1 represent the lockdown starting time and duration, respectively. Tmin is the minimum lockdown duration to make the lockdown policies effective. The quantity τ2 represents the duration of the post-lockdown phase;

• the parameters μ1, μ2 ≥ 1 accounts for possible differences in terms of economic impact between the lockdown and post-lockdown phases;

s(0) and s(T) are, respectively, the fractions of the population susceptible at the beginning and the end of the analysis.

We would like to make additional comments concerning the parameter μ1, μ2. The motivation for introducing μ1, μ2 is two-fold. First, after lockdown, people are more aware and act more responsibly than before lockdown. This means that automatic and costless population distancing typically occurs (8, 20, 21). Taking μ1, μ2 ≥ 1 precisely amounts to having a smaller reproduction number without any cost for the government. Additionally, as people typically tend to relax their effort to implement the epidemic management measures as time passes, it makes sense to assume that μ1 ≥ μ2 in our model. It also allows one to account for the fact that, after lockdown, the economic activity grows after the lockdown and the effects of the pandemic starts vanishing. This means that, in some sense we ignore memory effects due to lockdown measures. Further refinements of the proposed model might be considered to account for the lockdown memory effects. This is out of the scope of the present paper but we believe that, this would correspond to assuming μi < 1.

2.4. 4-Phase Optimal Control With Piecewise Constant Control Actions

Solving analytically the optimization problem given by (5) is not trivial. However, since we restrict our attention to a certain class of control policies, the problem turns out to be solvable through exhaustive search. Assuming the attenuation factor a0) = a1) = a2) = 1 (no attenuation at the beginning of each phase) and a constant control action in each phase, by using the relation u(t) = δ[R0R(t)], the OP (5) can be rewritten under a more convenient form for numerical purposes:

minimize  (τ0,τ1,τ2,R1,R2,R3){αKeδ2(R0-R1)2τ1+αKeδ2(R0-R2)2τ2μ12+αKeδ2(R0-R3)2[T-(τ0+τ1+τ2)]μ22+(1-α)Kh[s(0)-s(T)]}subject to   t[0,T], σNi(t)NmaxICU                       τ1Tmin                       R2>R1+0.2                       Equations (1) and (2).    (6)

where Ri represents the desired or target reproduction number over Phase i ∈ {1, 2, 3} without considering the attenuation factor (also, it is the reproduction number at the start of i-th phase). The second constraint is introduced here as there is a gap between lockdown reproduction number and after lockdown reproduction number. Finally, the conversion factors Ke and Kh are chosen as follows. The rationale behind the choice of Ke is that when choosing α = 1 the GDP loss should correspond to the best estimations made by economists. The GDP loss over the lockdown period for a given country is denoted by ΔGDP, the conversion factor Ke is chosen as follows:

Keδ2(R0-R1)2τ1=ΔGDP.    (7)

For France for example, the GDP loss during the lockdown has been evaluated (on April 20) to be around 120 billions € according to the OFCE (22). At last, the constant Kh is merely chosen as Kh = N, that is, when α = 0 the cost function corresponds to the number of people infected over the considered period of time.

3. Results

3.1. General Simulation Setup

To perform exhaustive search over the sextuple of variables (τ0, τ1, τ2, R1, R2, R3), time and amplitudes are quantized; we thus use hat notations to indicate corresponding values are quantized. Time is discretized with a step of 24 h (that is, one sample for each day) and a time horizon of T^=300 days (which approximately corresponds to 10 months that is the interval [March 1st, December 31th], for the tradeoff figure presented in section 3.4, for computational convenience, we take T^=210 days corresponding to 7 months from March 1st to September 30th) is assumed. The sets for the possible lockdown starting days, the lockdown duration (in days), post-lockdown phase duration, and the reproduction numbers are as follows: τ^0{1,2,...,30}, τ^1{Tmin,Tmin+1,...,90}, τ^2{1,2,...,120}, R^1{0.4,0.2,...,1.5}, R^2{0.4,0.2,...,1.5}, R^3{0.4,0.2,...,1.5}. Excluding Figure 5, due to the physical characteristics of the epidemics in France, we set Tmin = 30 because the lockdown duration is at least 4 weeks or 1 month to make the lockdown effective in real systems (23, 24)1. The SEIR model parameters are as follows: 1δ=10.1857=5.4 days, 1γ=10.16=6.25 days; these choices are consistent with many works and in particular the studies performed for France (25) and Italy (16). The population size is set to N = 66.106, the maximum number of patients requiring intensive care is set to NmaxICU=15.103, and σ = 1.5% (23, 24)1. Notice that this number is only reached for very small values of α (for which the total number of people infected over the analysis duration would be around 9 millions). The exposed population on March 1 2020 is initialized to Ne(0) = 1.33.105. This number is obtained from analyzing the data provided in (23). We consider the number of reported deaths at a given time to be a more reliable way of tracking the evolution of the pandemic rather than the reported number of infected people. Indeed, as soon as one examines absolute values, they typically become irrelevant. For example, during lockdown, because of the lack of tests and measurements, the real number of infected people was much higher than the official number. Now, even when tests were performed intensively, because of false positives, the absolute number of infected were again completely unreliable. For a prevalence of 1/1, 000 and a test reliability of 5% of false positives we see that the number of infected for 1,000 people is declared to be about 50 whereas the actual number of infected is only 1. Motivated by these critical issues, we have considered figures which are much more reliable such as the number of deceases due to Covid-19 in France (23, 25). From the number of deaths and the global average rate (worldwide) of the mortality rate (in the range 0.3–0.5% when averaged over classes of ages and countries), the reconstructed number of infected people turns out to be more accurate. Therefore, by fixing the mortality rate to a given value [in (25) for instance, the mortality rate averaged over all the classes of infected people is evaluated to be around 0.53% for France], one can estimate the exposed and infected population size 3–4 weeks before the measured number of deaths due to Covid-19. For our computation, the initial conditions of the ordinary differential equations (ODE) equations are chosen as s(0) = 1 − e(0), i(0) = r(0) = 0, and the ODE is solved by using the Matlab ode45 solver. Concerning the economic cost for France related to Covid-19, the GDP loss over the lockdown period is estimated by the OFCE (22) to be 120 billions € and we have, as reliable figures, that τ1France=55 days with R0France=3.5 and R1France=0.6. We therefore take Ke=7.379.109 €/day. Values of the reproduction number for the first two phases come from past and quite accurate evaluations [see e.g., (24)]. The value R2France=0.9 is less accurate and corresponds to the assumption that the government has been aiming at giving as much as freedom to the population while avoiding a second wave. Based on available statistics on Covid-19 in France1, the attenuation coefficients of the drift model have been chosen as follows: a1 = 0.1%, a2 = 0.2%, a3 = 0.2%. Unless stated otherwise, the economic impact parameters are chosen as μ1 = 1.41 (i.e., μ12~2) and μ2 = 1.3. Also, when α is assumed to be fixed, it is set to 10−4.

To justify the choice of the attenuation parameters, that is, a1 = 0.1%, a2 = 0.2%, a3 = 0.2%, we apply the French policy into our model. By comparing the active cases obtained from our model and the official data, it can be illustrated in Figure 2 that our model matches well with the real data, especially in the second-half of the plot, where the number of tests conducted are sufficiently large. This validate the choice of our model and parameters. The mismatch on March and April are mainly due to the lacking number of tests that were taken during the early outbreak of the pandemic, leading to a much lower reported number of active cases.

FIGURE 2
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 2. Comparison between our model (blue curve) and the reported statistics (black curve) from March 1st to September 30th. When the number of tests are sufficiently large, our model matches well with the reported statistics. The reproduction number is linearly increasing during each phase, and is discontinuous during the transition between phases.

3.2. Optimal Tradeoff Between Economic and Health Impacts

With the proposed government decision-making model, implementing a desired tradeoff between the health cost and economic cost merely amounts to choosing a given value for the parameter α. Figure 3 depicts for various values of α in the interval [10−7, 10−4] the total GDP loss and number of infected people that is obtained after choosing the (quantized version of the) sextuple (τ0, τ1, τ2, R1, R2, R3) that minimizes the combined cost given by Equation (6). At one extreme, when α is relatively large (α = 10−4) (that is, when the government aims at minimizing the economic cost in the first place—always under the ICU capacity constraint) we see that the best epidemic management strategy leads to a GDP loss over the entire study period [March 1, September 30] is about 206 billions € with 7.16 millions infected, and 15, 000 patients requiring intensive care. At the other extreme, when α is relatively small (α = 10−7), the GDP loss reaches values as high as 295 billion € with a total number of newly infected people over the period [March 1, September 30] as low as 23, 162. To evaluate the efficiency of the epidemic management strategy of the French government policy, we have represented the point corresponding to the estimated number of infected people and GDP loss by September 30; with our model, the GDP loss over the period of time of interest is 241 billion € and the total number of infected people is about 6.88 million. What the best tradeoff curve indicates is that there were management policies that would allow the French government to have a better “performance” both in terms of GDP loss and the number of infected people. For instance, we indicate a point for which it would have been possible to have about 1.05 million people infected (that is, about 6 times less than what is estimated with the current policy) while ensuring a total GDP loss of 231 billions €. Which type of epidemic management strategy should be used to have such an outcome? The next sections provide a detailed analysis of the features of the optimal strategy.

FIGURE 3
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 3. The plots represent the possible tradeoffs between health cost (measured in terms of the total number of infected people) and economic cost (measured in terms of GDP loss) that can be obtained (by choosing the best epidemic management policy). In particular, with the assumed model, it is seen, in retrospect, that it would have been possible to divide the number of infected people by about 6 while saving about 10 billions € in terms of GDP with the optimal 4-phase strategy.

3.3. Optimal Features of the Optimal Epidemic Management Strategy

One of the important features for controlling the Covid-19 epidemic which has been well-commented in newspapers in various countries is the lockdown starting time. To minimize the health cost, the answer is ready: the lockdown phase should always start as soon as possible. But when one wants to realize a tradeoff between health and economic costs, the answer is less immediate. For different values for μ1 and μ2, Figure 4 provides the best day to start locking down the population, for one hundred values of α ranging from 10−4 to 10−6. The main message of this figure is that, even for (relatively) large values for α (that is, when the economic cost dominates the health cost), the optimal lockdown starting day should be before March 4th (i.e., τ0 ≤ 4). This clearly shows that, once an epidemic has been declared, invoking economic damages to delay the lockdown phase is not acceptable. Note that this conclusion holds when economic losses are assumed to be uniform over time (μ1 = μ2 = 1). When the economic cost associated with a given intensity or severity level is lower after lockdown than during it (here μ1 = 1.41 and μ2 = 1.3), it is always optimal to start locking down as soon as possible. Note that our model does not capture the possible fact that population needs to be psychologically prepared to follow the lockdown measures. In France, by March 17, there were official figures about the epidemic which were sufficiently critical to make the population accept the measures whereas, starting on March 4 (the optimal starting date for μ1 = μ2 = 1) the situation might have not been critical enough to create full adhesion to government measures.

FIGURE 4
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 4. When economic losses are assumed to be uniform over time (μ = 1), there is some economic incentive to delay the lockdown, but this delay is seen to be at maximum 4 days. When economic losses are lower after lockdown than during it, it is beneficial to start the lockdown faster, up to 3 days delay.

A second key feature of the Covid-19 epidemic control strategy was the lockdown phase duration namely, the value of τ1. To better explore the relationship between τ1 and α (the tradeoff), we relax the lockdown duration constraint here and set Tmin = 1. For (μ1, μ2) = (1, 1) and (μ1, μ2) = (1.41, 1.3), Figure 5 provides the optimal lockdown duration (in days) for values of α ranging from 10−4 to 10−6. For (μ1, μ2) = (1, 1) (i.e., when economic losses are uniform over time), the optimal duration ranges from 53 to 83 days for a large fraction of the considered interval for α. Interestingly, we see that these values are relatively close to the lockdown duration effectively imposed in France namely 55 days. For larger values of μ1 and μ2, the optimal lockdown duration is seen to be much smaller. Therefore, if economic losses are uniform over time, the French government policy seems to be very coherent. On the other hand, if the economic impact is smaller after lockdown, our study suggests shorter lockdown durations. In fact, our results show the existence of a critical value for the tradeoff parameter α above which the second phase of the management of the epidemic should not be present. This means that the optimal control consists of three phases instead of four.

FIGURE 5
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 5. When economic losses are assumed to be uniform over time (μ = 1), it is optimal to have a long lockdown (typically between 60 and 80 days) whatever the tradeoff desired. But, if the economic losses of the third phase are less than during lockdown, the lockdown phase should be shorter.

To conclude this section, let us consider Figure 6. For the by default scenario studied in this paper [(μ1, μ2) = (1.41, 1.3), α = 10−4], the figure represents the evolution of number of infected people, that is, Ni(t), and the transmission rate when the optimal policy is adopted. First, it is seen that for the health-economic tradeoff corresponding to α = 10−4, there is no interest in delaying the lockdown phase. By “lockdown” phase, the authors mean that it might be any type of phase for which the reproduction number is as low as 0.4 (vs. the estimated 0.6 in France); very efficient digital tracing and intensive use of face masks is also an option which has been successfully adopted in countries such as South Korea [see e.g., (26)]. The optimal lockdown phase duration is seen to be about 1 month (instead of 2 for France). We see that the existence of an adjustment phase is part of the optimal policy. For this point, we see that the adjustment phase should have occurred much before in France (end of June vs. end of September). The next section is precisely dedicated to the impact of the adjustment phase.

FIGURE 6
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 6. This figure represents the evolution of number of infected people [Ni(t)] and the transmission rate when the optimal policy is adopted.

3.4. Lockdown Policies With Different R0

Since the natural reproduction number R0 depends on temperatures, population density, may vary over time due to mutation effects, and in any case is not known perfectly, it is of interest to study the impact of R0 on the obtained characteristics for the optimal epidemic management policy. This is what Figure 7 represents. It is seen that large variations on R0 do not involve large variations on the starting day. For instance, moving from R0 = 2 to R0 = 3.5 only changes the optimal date by 1 day (Day 2 instead of Day 3), which confirms the need to act fastly even when the transmission is more limited (e.g., thanks to higher temperatures or lower population density). Note that this holds even if the economic impact is accounted for. It is also good for economical aspects to react fastly to an epidemics. For the optimal reproduction number during lockdown (namely, R1) it is also seen that moving a scenario in which R0 = 2 to R0 = 3.5 does not change very significantly the results: the target severity (or freedom) level would correspond to R1 = 0.4 instead R1 = 0.6, which shows that the severity should be high during lockdown even in countries or regions where transmission is more limited.

FIGURE 7
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 7. Comparison of lockdown policies with different R0. When the situation is worse, a sooner and more strict lockdown strategy should be applied.

Alternatively, the impact of R0 uncertainty can be evaluated by adding a perturbation on R0. It is assumed that what is known to determine the optimal parameters is R^0=R0+Δ, Δ being a Gaussian noise Δ~N(0,σ2). The reproduction number have to stay in a given interval of physical relevance of the form [Rmin, Rmax]. Thus, the noise is imposed to stay in the interval [−R0 + Rmin, −R0 + Rmax]. With R0 = 3.5, Rmin = 1 and Rmax = 4, Figure 8 depicts the average bias for τ0 and R1 induced by uncertainty on R0. The average biases for τ0 and R1 are defined by 𝔼Δ[|R^1-R1|] and 𝔼Δ[|τ^0-τ0|], where R^1 and τ^0 are obtained with the noisy reproduction number R^0. Remarkably, the impact of the corresponding noise on the results is seen to be very reasonable and does not affect the main conclusions drawn in the first version of the paper. This indicates that the conducted analysis is robust against some forms of uncertainties. But of course, as mentioned previously, a deeper analysis would be required to state more general conclusions.

FIGURE 8
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 8. Influence of uncertainties on R0 on the optimal values for τ0 and R1.

In addition, a more global sensitivity analysis to other SEIR model parameters, i.e, δ and γ, have been conducted by simulations. A similar conclusion can be drawn. This shows that our conclusions are quite robust to effects such as parameter uncertainties. This is in part due to the fact that we are mostly seeking discrete parameters and not continuous parameters, which creates a form of robustness.

3.5. Impact of the Adjustment Phase

Always for the typical scenario presented in the general setting part, Figure 9 depicts the evolution of the number of infected people (in France) for the policy effectively implemented over the period [March 1, September 30]. Here, only the adjustment phase is assumed to be optimizable. The figure allows one to quantify the impact of the severity level of the adjustment phase. Without the adjustment phase, the fraction of infected people is such that the number of people requiring intensive care exceeds the double of the maximum ICU capacity of France. However, by implementing measures such that R(t) < 1.2 over the adjustment phase, the constraint on the ICU capacity is not violated by the end of 2020. Furthermore, to avoid the overwhelming health service for a longer time, it is better to implement measures such that R(t) < 1 over the adjustment phase since the fraction of infected people will be non-increasing with R(t) < 1.

FIGURE 9
www.frontiersin.org

Figure 9. The figure shows the impact of the adjustment phase. Only by imposing R(t) < 1.2 over this phase, the number of people admitted in ICU does not exceed the capacity of France by the end of 2020.

4. Discussion

In this work, we propose to model the behavior of a government as far as the epidemic control is concerned. The proposed model, despite its simplicity, has the merit of being able to capture the fundamental tradeoff between economic and health aspects. Obviously, to capture other effects such as the psychological effects of measures on people, a more general model should be considered. The proposed model allows one to provide quantitative answers to issues which have been well-commented in the media. For example, even when a government chooses to assign a high value to the economic aspect, it is seen that the best strategy is almost always to implement a severe phase as soon as possible. This severe phase involves locking the population down, as most countries did, or to make intensive use of digital tracing and face masks as South Korea did. In the latter case, a loss in terms of privacy is the price to be paid for having more freedom. When inspecting the obtained numerical results performed for France, it is seen that the optimal features for the lockdown/severe phase require targeting a reproduction number smaller than the one achieved in France (0.4 vs. 0.6), while having a shorter duration for the severe phase (1 month instead of 2). Note that some countries adopted measures which were more severe than France. For instance, China has been imposing the use of a given food supply system which was very efficient in terms of epidemic mitigation (2729). Then, by planning an adjustment phase at the right time, we have seen that as a final result, the number of infected people can be reduced by a factor of 6 when compared to the current French policy (1.05 million of infected instead of 6.88 millions for the current policy) while having similar GDP losses (231 billions € instead of 241 billions €). We have seen that by considering a simple model as we have studied, the need for an adjustment phase could have been anticipated. Such a phase is necessary to avoid the number of patients under intensive care exceeding the capacity of the ICUs. Also, because of the natural tendency of humans to deviate from rules over time, it appears that measures should be updated about every month and not less frequently.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/supplementary material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author/s.

Author Contributions

SL, CZ, VV, and IM designed the proposed model. SL and CZ conducted the review of the related literature. SL collected the data to calibrate the assumed model. CZ and SL performed the simulations. All authors contributed to the writing of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was partially supported by ANR via the grant NICETWEET, number ANR-20-CE48-0009.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Acknowledgments

The authors acknowledge the support of the French National Research Agency ANR and the French National Research Center CNRS. Part of this manuscript has been released as a pre-print at medRxiv (30).

Footnotes

1. ^Santé Publique France. Available online at: www.santepubliquefrance.fr.

References

1. Peng L, Yang W, Zhang D, Zhuge C, Hong L. Epidemic analysis of COVID-19 in China by dynamical modeling. arXiv [Preprint]. arXiv:2002.06563.

PubMed Abstract | Google Scholar

2. Pribylova L, Hajnova V. SEIAR model with asymptomatic cohort and consequences to efficiency of quarantine government measures in COVID-19 epidemic. arXiv [Preprint]. arXiv:2004.02601.

Google Scholar

3. Victor A. Estimation of the probability of reinfection with COVID-19 coronavirus by the SEIRUS model. medRxiv. (2020). doi: 10.1101/2020.04.02.20050930

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

4. Giordano G, Blanchini F, Bruno R, Colaneri P, Di Filippo A, Di Matteo A, et al. A SIDARTHE model of COVID-19 epidemic in Italy. arXiv [Preprint]. arXiv: 2003.09861.

Google Scholar

5. Roques L, Klein EK, Papaïx J, Sar A, Soubeyrand S. Impact of lockdown on the epidemic dynamics of COVID-19 in France. Front Med. (2020) 7:274. doi: 10.3389/fmed.2020.00274

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

6. Di Domenico L, Pullano G, Coletti P, Hens N, Colizza V. Expected impact of school closure and telework to mitigate COVID-19 epidemic in France. Report #8. March 14, (2020). Available online at: https://www.epicx-lab.com/uploads/9/6/9/4/9694133/inserm_covid-19-school-closure-french-regions_20200313.pdf (accessed April 28, 2020).

PubMed Abstract | Google Scholar

7. Khawaja AP, Warwick AN, Hysi PG, Kastner A, Dick A, Khaw PT, et al. Associations with Covid-19 hospitalisation amongst 406,793 adults: the UK Biobank prospective cohort study. medRxiv [Preprint]. (2020). doi: 10.1101/2020.05.06.20092957

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

8. Atkeson A. What Will Be the Economic Impact of Covid-19 in the US? Rough Estimates of Disease Scenarios. National Bureau of Economic Research (2020). doi: 10.3386/w26867

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

9. Eichenbaum MS, Rebelo S, Trabandt M. The Macroeconomics of Epidemics. National Bureau of Economic Research (2020). doi: 10.3386/w26882

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

10. Baldwin R, Di Mauro BW. Economics in the time of COVID-19. VOX CEPR Policy Portal (2020).

Google Scholar

11. Fernandes N. Economic effects of coronavirus outbreak (COVID-19) on the world economy. Social Science Research Network (2020). doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3557504

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

12. McKibbin WJ, Fernando R. The global macroeconomic impacts of COVID-19: seven scenarios. CAMA Working Paper No. 19/2020 (2020). doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3547729

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

13. Zakary O, Rachik M, Elmouki I. On the analysis of a multi-regions discrete SIR epidemic model: an optimal control approach. Int J Dyn Control. (2017) 5:917–30. doi: 10.1007/s40435-016-0233-2

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

14. Alvarez FE, Argente D, Lippi F. A Simple Planning Problem for Covid-19 Lockdown. National Bureau of Economic Research (2020). doi: 10.3386/w26981

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

15. Boujakjian H. Modeling the spread of Ebola with SEIR and optimal control. SIAM Undergrad Res. (2016) 9:299–310. doi: 10.1137/16S015061

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

16. Casella F. Can the COVID-19 epidemic be managed on the basis of daily data? arXiv [Preprint]. arXiv:2003.06967.

Google Scholar

17. Rawson T, Brewer T, Veltcheva D, Huntingford C, Bonsall MB. How and when to end the COVID-19 lockdown: an optimization approach. Front Public Health. (2020) 8:262. doi: 10.3389/fpubh.2020.00262

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

18. Dagnall N, Drinkwater KG, Denovan A, Walsh RS. Bridging the gap between UK Government strategic narratives and public opinion/behavior: Lessons from COVID-19. Front Commun. (2020) 5:71. doi: 10.3389/fcomm.2020.00071

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

19. Anzum R, Islam MZ. Mathematical modeling of coronavirus reproduction rate with policy and behavioral effects. medRxiv [Preprint]. (2020). doi: 10.1101/2020.06.16.20133330

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

20. Greenstone M, Nigam V. Does Social Distancing Matter? University of Chicago, Becker Friedman Institute for Economics Working Paper (2020). doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3561244

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

21. Andersen M. Early evidence on social distancing in response to COVID-19 in the United States. Social Science Research Network (2020). doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3569368

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

22. Observatoire français des conjonctures économiques (OFCE). Évaluation au 20 avril 2020 de l'impact économique de la pandémie de COVID-19 et des mesures de confinement en France. OFCE Policy Brief (2020).

PubMed Abstract | Google Scholar

23. Open Stats Coronavirus. Covid-19 Statistiques/France. Technical report (2020). Available online at: https://www.coronavirus-statistiques.com/stats-globale/covid-19-par-pays-nombre-de-cas/

24. Delfraissy JF, Atlani-Duault L, Benamouzig D, Bouadma L, Casanova JL, et al. Sortie Progressive de Confinement: Prérequis et mesures Phares. Conseil Scientifique Covid-19 (2020).

Google Scholar

25. Salje H, Kiem CT, Lefrancq N, Courtejoie N, Bosetti P, Paireau J, et al. Estimating the burden of SARS-CoV-2 in France. Science. (2020). doi: 10.1126/science.abc3517

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

26. Park YJ, Choe YJ, Park O, Park SY, Kim YM, Kim J, et al. Contact tracing during coronavirus disease outbreak, South Korea, 2020. Emerg Infect Dis. (2020) 26:2465–8. doi: 10.3201/eid2610.201315

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

27. Wu Z, McGoogan JM. Characteristics of and important lessons from the coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) outbreak in China: summary of a report of 72 314 cases from the Chinese Center for Disease Control and Prevention. JAMA. (2020) 323:1239–42. doi: 10.1001/jama.2020.2648

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

28. Lau H, Khosrawipour V, Kocbach P, Mikolajczyk A, Schubert J, Bania J, et al. The positive impact of lockdown in Wuhan on containing the COVID-19 outbreak in China. J Travel Med. (2020) 27:taaa037. doi: 10.1093/jtm/taaa037

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

29. Fang H, Wang L, Yang Y. Human Mobility Restrictions and the Spread of the Novel Coronavirus (2019-ncov) in China. National Bureau of Economic Research (2020). doi: 10.3386/w26906

PubMed Abstract | CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

30. Lasaulce S, Varma VS, Morarescu C, Siying L. How efficient are the lockdown measures taken for mitigating the Covid-19 epidemic? medRxiv. (2020). doi: 10.1101/2020.06.02.20120089

CrossRef Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: epidemic, COVID-19, SARS-CoV2, SEIR model, epidemic management strategy, behavior model

Citation: Lasaulce S, Zhang C, Varma V and Morărescu IC (2021) Analysis of the Tradeoff Between Health and Economic Impacts of the Covid-19 Epidemic. Front. Public Health 9:620770. doi: 10.3389/fpubh.2021.620770

Received: 27 October 2020; Accepted: 11 February 2021;
Published: 05 March 2021.

Edited by:

Babak A. Ardekani, Nathan Kline Institute for Psychiatric Research, United States

Reviewed by:

Juliette Unwin, Imperial College London, United Kingdom
Didier Georges, Grenoble Institute of Technology, France

Copyright © 2021 Lasaulce, Zhang, Varma and Morărescu. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Chao Zhang, zhangchaohust@gmail.com

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.