Next Article in Journal
Effect of Land Use and Cover Change on Air Quality in Urban Sprawl
Next Article in Special Issue
Wind Power Deployment: The Role of Public Participation in the Decision-Making Process in Ontario, Canada
Previous Article in Journal
Study on Industrial Integration Development of the Energy Chemical Industry in Urumqi-Changji-Shihezi Urban Agglomeration, Xinjiang, NW China
Previous Article in Special Issue
SME’s Appropriability Regime for Sustainable Development-the Role of Absorptive Capacity and Inventive Capacity
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Contract Coordination Strategy of Supply Chain with Substitution under Supply Disruption and Stochastic Demand

College of Mathematics and Statistics, Northwest Normal University, Lanzhou 730070, Gansu, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2016, 8(7), 676; https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su8070676
Submission received: 21 April 2016 / Revised: 1 July 2016 / Accepted: 8 July 2016 / Published: 18 July 2016
(This article belongs to the Special Issue How Better Decision-Making Helps to Improve Sustainability - Part II)

Abstract

:
Based on two substitute products, we study the inventory and contract coordination strategy of a three-echelon supply chain, which consists of two suppliers, a manufacturer and a retailer, under supply disruption and stochastic demand. We investigate the channel gross profit model of the centralized supply chain and obtain a unique optimal order quantity. Under a decentralized decision, we find that the commonly-used wholesale price contracts cannot coordinate the system. Then, we propose a buy-back contract and prove that this contract can more efficiently coordinate the system than the former. At last, we show that the integrated performance of the decentralized system can be maximized through choosing the buy-back parameter by the manufacturer and reveal that the effects of supply uncertainty and the substitution behavior of customers on the optimal decision by numerical examples.

1. Introduction

As the globalization of the economy accelerated, today’s supply chains span the globe with the unexpected changes in market demands and uncertainties of supply. These changes and uncertainties not only increase risks, but also reduce visibility that, in turn, makes supply chain operations more vulnerable to unforeseen disruptions. A supply chain might suffer from major supply disruptions caused by web server internal errors, storms, strikes, workforce reduction, natural disasters, etc. A supply disruption not only directly affects the supplier, but also results in significant loss to the downstream members of the supply chain (Li et al. [1]). For example, the earthquake in Japan in 2011 caused Japan’s new vehicle sales in April to be halved, sinking to the lowest monthly tally on record. Sales of cars fell 51 percent from the year before, and market leader Toyota put in the worst performance with a 69 percent drop. That is because domestic auto manufacturers felt the full brunt of the 11 March earthquake, which caused unprecedented disruption to car production. Those natural disasters had exerted some serious effects on supply chain management.
Reflecting growing concerns over supply chain disruptions, supply chain risk management has become an emerging research topic (Kihyun et al. [2]). Generally, a coordinated decentralized supply chain usually performs better than an uncoordinated one (Chen et al. [3]). Supply chain contracts could provide its coordination; it can also be called coordination in a decentralized supply chain if and only if the total channel profit of the decentralized supply chain of that contract is equal to the centralized supply chain system. The study of the contract strategy has a significant and practical meaning for the supply chain system; recently, scholars have obtained a series of impressive and practical results in related research fields. Interested readers may refer to Liu and Li [4], Shin and Benton [5], Zhou [6] and Arcelus et al. [7]. In our paper, we specially consider two kinds of supply chain contracts, wholesale price contracts and buy-back contracts, and implement the two contracts for a three-echelon supply chain in terms of both supply disruption and stochastic demand.
The above observations provide us the motivation for the current work. In this paper, we focus on three areas of research: research on supply disruption, research on the inventory model with substitution and research on the contract in a supply chain with stochastic demand. Integrating supply disruption, the inventory model with substitution and contract coordination into one system is the innovation of the article. This paper intends to answer the following questions:
(1)
How does the supply disruption impact the integrated performance?
(2)
How does the dual replacement influence the profit of each member and the total profit of the system?
(3)
How do the wholesale price contract and buy-back contract coordinate the supply chain system of substitute products?
(4)
Which contract strategy could make the channel gross profit recovered?
(5)
How does one decide the buy-back price in order to make the channel gross profit recovered?
To answer these questions, we build a three-echelon supply chain setting in which two suppliers provide the components for a manufacturer; then the manufacturer assembles the products; after having been assembled, the manufacturer provides the products for the retailer, who sells the final products to consumers. When the supplier S 1 encounters a supply disruption risk, the manufacturer sends out the order to the spot market immediately and then provides the retailer with substitute products. In this paper, we aim to study the coordinated role of the contract decision on the three-echelon supply chain based on substitute products and how to decide the buy-back price to make the performance under a decentralized decision return to the level of the centralized supply chain.
The contribution of this paper contains four parts. First, we obtain a unique optimal order quantity of the centralized supply chain by analyzing the channel gross profit function. Second, under the decentralized decision, we find that the commonly-used wholesale price contracts cannot coordinate the system, and then, we propose a buy-back contract, which can more efficiently coordinate the system than the former. Third, we explore the effects of supply uncertainty and the substitution behavior of customers on the optimal decision of each member through numerical analysis. Fourth, we also illustrate that the integrated performance of the decentralized system can be maximized through choosing the buy-back parameter by the manufacturer.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, we review the relevant literature. Section 3 gives us the model description, assumptions and symbols used in the paper. Section 4 presents the model under centralized decision-making. In Section 5 and Section 6, we examine the maximal profit of each member under the decentralized decision in the case of the wholesale price contract and the buy-back contract, respectively, and analyze the impact of contract parameter on the total profit of the decentralized supply chain. Section 7 demonstrates that the manufacturer makes the supply chain more coordinated through controlling the parameter by using numerical examples. The last section summarizes our research findings and future directions.

2. Literature Review

This paper is closely related to disruption management and supply chain coordination management. We review the literature that is representative and particularly relevant to our study.
A great number of articles on supply chain systems always assumed that supply is reliable, namely the quantity of supply equals the quantity of ordering. However, in real commercial activities, the supply disruption of supply chain upstream enterprises is always inevitable because of the influence from various indefinite factors and risks, such as equipment failures, natural disasters, unexpected social events, etc. Serel [8] explored an extension of the single-period (newsboy) inventory problem when supply is uncertain. Qi et al. [9] investigated a continuous-review inventory problem for a retailer who faces random disruptions both internally and externally (from its supplier). Hou et al. [10] studied a buy-back contract between a buyer and a backup supplier when the buyer’s main supplier experiences disruptions. Sargnt and Qi [11] studied a continuous-review inventory problem of a two-echelon supply chain with random supply and retailer disruption. There are three approaches to characterize supply uncertainty (He et al. [12]). In our model, the supplier’s status shows the following two situations: one is the stochastic supply problem, which manifests the random function of ordering quantity; the other is the supply disruption, which means that supply quantity equals zero (Lou et al. [13]). We can group supply disruption into two general categories: one is that the supplier cannot provide components or products to the manufacturer; the other is that the supply of components or products is disrupted in the course of delivery from supplier to manufacturer (Zhang and Xie [14]). The two kinds of disruptions are contained in this paper. More relevant literature can be found in He and Zhao [15] and Shao [16].
Similar to the current literature on supply chain management, this paper assumes that the demand of goods is random. Market demand of some goods is generally unknown in practice. Although retailer make the decision on the market demand of goods according to the year’s experience of sales and the market database, this still lacks accuracy. Arcelus et al. [17] studied how a single manufacturer and retailer coordinate through a buy-back contract when market demand is uncertain. Hu et al. [18] studied a flexible ordering policy among a manufacturer and a supplier with random yield and demand uncertainty. The assumption of random demand is more realistic.
There are some more specialized phenomena in the practical commodity transaction market, i.e., a number of products have a certain substitutability. The degree of substitution depends on the cost performance of the alternatives and the preference of consumers. Bassok et al. [19] studied a single period multi-product inventory problem with substitution and proportional costs and revenues. Balakrishnan and Geunes [20] described a dynamic-programming solution method to find the production and substitution quantities that satisfy given multi-period downstream demands at minimum total setup, production, conversion and holding cost. We only consider the unidirectional substitutability between the two goods unless otherwise stated in this paper.
In addition, the management and optimization of the supply chain are the focuses of the industry at present and, hence, are used as a tool to reduce negative environmental influence [21]; furthermore, they are the most popular research fields, as well. In fact, the essence lies in how to coordinate the profit of each member of the supply chain with the total profit of the whole chain. Pasternack [22] originally proposed the concept of supply chain contracts. Tsay [23] pointed out that the wholesale price contract is simple and easy to manage, but coordination between supplier and retailer cannot be realized in general. More research also proved the view above, such as Lariviere [24], Lariviere and Porteus [25] and He and Zhao [15]. Padmanabhan [26] showed that the buy-back contract could lead to the retailer making an irrational order quantity under fixed market demand. For example, in the clothing industry, the manufacturer buys back part of the unsold products to encourage the retailer to order a large quantity. Yao [27] discussed the influence of information symmetry and information asymmetry on the profit of the manufacturer and retailer under the buy-back contract. Yu et al. [28] discussed how the supply chain deals with emergencies under whole price contracts and buy-back contracts, respectively. Our work is most related to Yang et al. [29]. They considered the component-purchasing problem for a supply chain consisting of one retailer and two complementary suppliers with different lead times and showed that the supply chain can be coordinated if both suppliers offer a returns policy and Supplier S 1 charges an order cancellation penalty to the retailer. Our work differs from Yang’s, as we do not consider lead time and order cancellation penalty. Instead, we consider the inventory and contract coordination strategy in a three-echelon supply chain in terms of both supply disruption and stochastic demand based on two substitute products.
This paper is different from the existing research. The above papers on the supply chain only examined the order and coordination policy of a two-echelon supply chain involving a single supplier and a single retailer, and there are few papers on supply chain considering the three-echelon supply chain, which consists of multiple suppliers, a single manufacturer, a single retailer in terms of both supply disruption and stochastic demand; this paper closely relates to these points.

3. Model Description, Assumptions and Symbols

We model an assemble-to-order system involving two component suppliers, a single manufacturer and a single retailer under a single period. Before the beginning of the sales cycle (the primary inventory of the system is zero), the retailer works out Q units of ordering quantity according to the forecast of the market demands and places an order with the manufacturer in advance. After ordering, the retailer cannot change the quantity. The manufacturer makes its corresponding decision based on the order from the retailer and respectively orders Q units of necessary component a i ( i = 1 , 2 ) , which is offered by the supplier S i ( i = 1 , 2 ) . The final product A is assembled out of components a 1 and a 2 . Each supplier only provides one kind of component, and the assembly ratio of component a 1 to a 2 is 1 : 1 . Supplier S i decides the wholesale price w i of component a i ( i = 1 , 2 ) . Once the necessary components are delivered, the manufacturer starts to assemble product A immediately. After this is accomplished, it will be sent to the retailer at once. Suppose that the market demand of product A a X, and denote the CDF and PDF of X by F ( x ) and f ( x ) , respectively. This form of assumption has been used in Christos and George [30], Anastasios et al. [31] and He and Zhao [15]. The above supply chain can be modeled as in Figure 1.
When the supply of component a 1 is suddenly disrupted with probability p before the start of the production period, the contingency plan replacing a 1 with the other component a 3 is urgently activated by the manufacturer. The manufacturer sends out Q units of the order of component a 3 to the spot market at once (the supply capacity is unlimited). The spot market decides the whole price w s of component a 3 . After the upgrade product A u is assembled, it will be delivered to the retailer. The manufacturer decides the wholesale price w m of product A or product A u .
After the sales cycle begins, on account of the shortage of product A, customers can choose whether to purchase its upgrade product A u according to their needs or preferences. That is, product A can be replaced by its upgrade product A u . We describe the substitution behavior of customers with probability β in this paper. Obviously, the market demands of product A u will be β X . Relevant notations are shown in Table 1.
We make the following assumptions to eliminate unrealistic cases.
Assumption 1. The system is risk-neutral; market information is symmetrical; and the decision-maker is entirely rational.
Assumption 2. The price s u of A u is not less than the price s of A, namely s u s .
Assumption 3. s > w m > c m + w 1 + w 2 > c m + c 1 + c 2 .
Assumption 4. s u > w m > c m + w s + w 2 > c m + c s + c 2 .
Assumption 5. w s > c s , w 1 > c 1 , w 2 > c 2 , c s > c 2 > c 1 .
The assumptions above guarantee that the retailer, the manufacturer and the suppliers are willing to participate in the market. Similar forms of those assumptions have been widely used by many authors (e.g., He et al. [12], He and Zhao [15]), which are realistic.

4. The Performance of the Supply Chain under the Centralized Decision

In this section, we first obtain the expected profit function model of a three-echelon supply chain in terms of supply disruption and stochastic demand under centralized decision-making and then analyze the retailer’s optimal decision on the order quantity.
Based on the assumptions above, when the supply of supplier S 1 is normal, the channel gross profit is:
Π c N = s min ( X , Q ) - c m Q - c 1 Q - c 2 Q - h ( Q - X ) + - c ( X - Q ) +
where the first term is the total sales revenue for product A, the second term is the manufacturing cost of the manufacturer and the third and fourth terms are the cost of supplier S i producing component a i ( i = 1 , 2 ) . The last two terms are holding cost and shortage cost.
When the supply of component a 1 is suddenly disrupted with probability p, the channel gross profit is:
Π c D = s u min ( β X , Q ) - c m Q - c s Q - c 2 Q - w Q - h ( Q - β X ) + - c ( β X - Q ) +
where the first term is the total sales revenue for product A u , the second term is the manufacturing cost of the manufacturer, the third term is the running cost of buying component a 3 of the spot market and the fourth term is the cost of supplier S 2 producing component a 2 . The fifth term is the lost cost of supplier S 1 because of disruption. The last two terms are holding cost and shortage cost.
Hence, the gross profit function of the supply chain under centralized decision-making is given by the following expression:
Π c = ( 1 - p ) Π c N + p Π c D = ( 1 - p ) [ s min ( X , Q ) - c m Q - c 1 Q - c 2 Q - h ( Q - X ) + - c ( X - Q ) + ] + p [ s u min ( β X , Q ) - c m Q - c s Q - c 2 Q - w Q - h ( Q - β X ) + - c ( β X - Q ) + ]
or, equivalently,
Π c = p [ ( s u β X - ( c m + c s + c 2 + w ) Q - h ( Q - β X ) ] + ( 1 - p ) [ ( s X - ( c m + c 1 + c 2 ) Q - h ( Q - X ) ] , 0 X < Q p [ ( s u β X - ( c m + c s + c 2 + w ) Q - h ( Q - β X ) ] + ( 1 - p ) [ ( s Q - ( c m + c 1 + c 2 ) Q - c ( X - Q ) ] , Q X < Q β p [ ( s u Q - ( c m + c s + c 2 + w ) Q - c ( β X - Q ) ] + ( 1 - p ) [ ( s Q - ( c m + c 1 + c 2 ) Q - c ( X - Q ) ] , Q β X
Consequently, the expected profit function of the integrated supply chain can be expressed as:
E [ Π c ] = E [ p Π c D + ( 1 - p ) Π c N ] = p { 0 Q β [ ( s u β x - ( c m + c s + c 2 + w ) Q - h ( Q - β x ) ] f ( x ) d x + Q β + [ ( s u Q - ( c m + c s + c 2 + w ) Q - c ( β x - Q ) ] f ( x ) d x } + ( 1 - p ) { 0 Q [ ( s x - ( c m + c 1 + c 2 ) Q - h ( Q - x ) ] f ( x ) d x + Q + [ ( s Q - ( c m + c 1 + c 2 ) Q - c ( x - Q ) ] f ( x ) d x } = p ( s u + h + c ) 0 Q β ( β x - Q ) f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) 0 Q ( x - Q ) f ( x ) d x + p ( s u + c 1 - s - c s - w ) Q - ( c m + c 1 + c 2 - s - c ) Q - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p )
Thus,
d E [ Π c ] d Q = - p ( s u + h + c ) 0 Q β f ( x ) d x - ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) 0 Q f ( x ) d x + p ( s u + c 1 - s - c s - w ) - ( c m + c 1 + c 2 - s - c )
Note that:
d 2 E [ Π c ] d Q 2 = - p ( s u + h + c ) f ( Q β ) 1 β - ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) f ( Q ) 0
from the first order conditions of profit maximization, we obtain:
p ( s u + h + c ) F ( Q β ) + ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) F ( Q ) = p ( s u - s + c 1 - c s - w ) + ( s + c - c m - c 1 - c 2 )
Denote the optimal order quantity of the supply chain under centralized decision-making by Q c , and then, we have the following proposition.
Proposition 1. 
The expected profit function E [ Π c ] is concave in Q, and hence, there exists a unique Q c to maximize the integrated performance of the centralized supply chain, which satisfies Equation (2).
Substituting Equation (2) into Equation (1), we obtain the maximal expected profit of the centralized supply chain as:
E [ Π c * ] = p ( s u + h + c ) 0 Q c β β x f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) 0 Q c x f ( x ) d x - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p )
Proposition 1 indicates that the maximal profit function under centralized decision-making and the unique optimal order quantity exist. Hence, the main objective of the contract coordination in the decentralized supply chain is to make the order quantity of the retailer equal to Q c .

5. Analysis on the Decentralized Supply Chain Based on Wholesale Price Contracts

This section considers each member’s profit in the decentralized supply chain under wholesale price contracts. We first develop the expected profit function model of the retailer and then use backward induction to obtain the maximal expected profit of each member. Lastly, we obtain that wholesale price contracts cannot coordinate the decentralized supply chain in terms of both supply disruption and stochastic demand.

5.1. The Retailer’s Expected Profit and Decision-Making

Based on the assumptions above, given the wholesale price set by the supplier S i ( i = 1 , 2 ) and the manufacturer, respectively, the order quantity of the retailer and the profit function of the retailer are as follows.
When disruption occurs, the profit of the retailer is:
Π R D = s u min ( β X , Q ) - w m Q - h ( Q - β X ) + - c ( β X - Q ) +
where the first term is the total sales revenue for product A u , the second term is the purchase cost of A u , i.e., the revenue of manufacturer, the third term is holding cost and the fourth term is the shortage cost.
When supply works normally, the profit of the retailer is:
Π R N = s min ( X , Q ) - w m Q - h ( Q - X ) + - c ( X - Q ) +
where the first term is the total sales revenue for product A, the second term is the purchase cost of product A. The last two terms are the holding cost and shortage cost.
Hence, the expected profit function of the retailer can be expressed as:
E [ Π R w ] = E [ p Π R D + ( 1 - p ) Π R N ] = p { 0 Q β [ s u β x - w m Q - h ( Q - β x ) ] f ( x ) d x + Q β + [ Q ( s u - w m + c ) - c β x ] f ( x ) d x } + ( 1 - p ) { 0 Q [ s x - w m Q - h ( Q - x ) ] f ( x ) d x + Q + [ Q ( s - w m + c ) - c x ] f ( x ) d x }
Denote the optimal order quantity in the decentralized supply chain under wholesale price contracts by Q w .
Proposition 2. 
The expected profit function E [ Π R w ] is concave in Q, and the maximum, Q w , is uniquely solved by:
p ( s u + h + c ) F ( Q β ) + ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) F ( Q ) = p ( s u - s ) + ( c + s - w m )
The proof of Proposition 2, as well as the proofs of other propositions are given in the Appendix. Substituting Equation (5) into Equation (A1), we obtain the maximal expected profit of the retailer as:
E [ Π R w * ] = p ( s u + h + c ) 0 Q w β β x f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) 0 Q w x f ( x ) d x - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p )

5.2. The Expected Profit of the Supplier and Spot Market

Based on the assumptions and propositions above, we easily obtain that the maximal expected profit function of supplier S 1 is:
E [ Π S 1 w * ] = E [ ( 1 - p ) ( w 1 Q w - c 1 Q w ) - p w Q w ] = ( 1 - p ) ( w 1 - c 1 ) Q w - p w Q w
The maximal expected profit of supplier S 2 is:
E [ Π S 2 w * ] = E [ w 2 Q w - c 2 Q w ] = ( w 2 - c 2 ) Q w
and the maximal expected profit of spot market is:
E [ Π S M w * ] = E [ p ( w s Q w - c s Q w ) ] = p ( w s - c s ) Q w

5.3. The Expected Profit of Manufacturer

When the supply of supplier S 1 is normal, the profit of the manufacturer is:
Π M N = w m Q - c m Q - w 1 Q - w 2 Q
where the first term is the total revenue of the manufacturer, the second term is the manufacturing cost of the manufacturer and the third and fourth terms are the purchase cost of component a i ( i = 1 , 2 ) .
When the supply of component a 1 from supplier S 1 is disrupted with probability p, the profit of the manufacturer is:
Π M D = w m Q - c m Q - w s Q - w 2 Q
where the first term is the total revenue of the manufacturer, the second term is the manufacturing cost of the manufacturer, the third term is the cost of buying component a 3 from the spot market and the fourth term is the cost of supplier S 2 producing component a 2 .
Consequently, the expected profit function of the manufacturer can be expressed as:
E [ Π M w ] = E [ ( 1 - p ) Π M N + p Π M D ] = E [ ( 1 - p ) ( w m Q - c m Q - w 1 Q - w 2 Q ) + p ( w m Q - c m Q - w s Q - w 2 Q ) ]
Set Q = Q w ; we then obtain the maximal expected profit of the manufacturer as:
E [ Π M w * ] = ( 1 - p ) ( w m - c m - w 1 - w 2 ) Q w + p ( w m - c m - w s - w 2 ) Q w
Proposition 3. 
Under wholesale price contracts, the optimal order quantity in the decentralized supply chain, Q w , is less than that of the supply chain based on centralized decision-making, Q c , namely Q w Q c . Therefore, the wholesale price contracts cannot coordinate the decentralized supply chain.
Proposition 3 is similar to He and Zhao [15], so we thus omit the proof.

6. Analysis on Decentralized Supply Chain Based on Buy-Back Contracts

In this section, we mainly pay attention to the decentralized supply chain under buy-back contracts. It can be seen from the above analysis that wholesale price contracts cannot coordinate the decentralized supply chain. Thus, we consider the other contract, buy-back contracts, in order to coordinate the supply chain.
Buy-back contracts, also called the return policy, mean that when the order quantity of the retailer is greater than the current demands at the end of the sales cycle, the manufacturer buys back unsold products from the retailer to encourage the retailer to order a larger quantity at the beginning of the next selling season.

6.1. The Retailer’s Expected Profit and Decision-Making

When supplier S 1 supplies normally, the profit of the retailer is:
Π R N = s min ( X , Q ) - w m Q + b ( Q - X ) + - c ( X - Q ) +
where ( x - y ) + m a x { x - y , 0 } ; the first term is the total sales revenue for product A; the second term is the purchase cost of product A; the third term is the return values from the manufacturer; and the fourth term is the shortage cost.
When supply disruption occurs, the profit of the retailer is:
Π R D = s u min ( β X , Q ) - w m Q + b ( Q - β X ) + - c ( β X - Q ) +
where the first term is the total sales revenue for product A u ; the second term is the purchase cost of A u , i.e., the revenue of manufacturer, the third term is the return values from the manufacturer and the fourth term is the shortage cost.
Therefore, the expected profit function of the retailer can be expressed as:
E [ Π R b ] = E [ p Π R D + ( 1 - p ) Π R N ] = p { 0 Q β [ s u β x - w m Q + b ( Q - β x ) ] f ( x ) d x + Q β + [ s u Q - w m Q - c ( β x - Q ) ] f ( x ) d x } + ( 1 - p ) { 0 Q [ s x - w m Q + b ( Q - x ) ] f ( x ) d x + Q + [ s Q - w m Q - c ( x - Q ) ] f ( x ) d x } = p ( b - c - s u ) 0 Q β ( Q - β x ) f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( b - c - s ) 0 Q ( Q - x ) f ( x ) d x + p ( s u - s ) Q + ( s + c - w m ) Q - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p )
Thus,
d E [ Π R b ] d Q = p ( b - c - s u ) 0 Q β f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( b - c - s ) 0 Q f ( x ) d x + p ( s u - s ) + ( s + c - w m )
Note that:
d 2 E [ Π R b ] d Q 2 = p ( b - c - s u ) f ( Q β ) 1 β + ( 1 - p ) ( b - c - s ) f ( Q ) 0
from the first order conditions of profit maximization, we obtain:
p ( s u + c - b ) F ( Q β ) + ( 1 - p ) ( s + c - b ) F ( Q ) = p ( s u - s ) + ( s + c - w m )
Denote the optimal order quantity in the decentralized supply chain under buy-back contracts by Q b ; we then have the following proposition.
Proposition 4. 
The expected profit function E [ Π R b ] is concave in Q, and the optimal order quantity Q b is uniquely derived through solving Equation (7).
Substituting Equation (7) into Equation (6), we obtain the maximal expected profit of the retailer as:
E [ Π R b * ] = p ( s u + c - b ) 0 Q b β β x f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( s + c - b ) 0 Q b x f ( x ) d x - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p )

6.2. The Supplier’s and Spot Market’s Expected Profit

Apparently, the maximal expected profit function of supplier S 1 is:
E [ Π S 1 b * ] = E [ ( 1 - p ) ( w 1 Q b - c 1 Q b ) - p w Q b ] = ( 1 - p ) ( w 1 - c 1 ) Q b - p w Q b
The maximal expected profit of supplier S 2 is:
E [ Π S 2 b * ] = E [ w 2 Q b - c 2 Q b ] = ( w 2 - c 2 ) Q b
and the maximal expected profit of the spot market is:
E [ Π S M b * ] = E [ p ( w s Q b - c s Q b ) ] = p ( w s - c s ) Q b

6.3. The Manufacturer’s Expected Profit

When the supply of supplier S 1 is normal, the profit of the manufacturer is:
Π M N = w m Q - c m Q - w 1 Q - w 2 Q - b ( Q - X ) + - h ( Q - X ) +
where the first term is the total revenue of the manufacturer, the second term is the manufacturing cost of the manufacturer, the third and fourth terms are the purchase cost of component a i ( i = 1 , 2 ) , the fifth term is the buy-back cost and the last term is the holding cost.
When the supply of component a 1 is disrupted with probability p, the profit of the manufacturer is:
Π M D = w m Q - c m Q - w s Q - w 2 Q - b ( Q - β X ) + - h ( Q - β X ) +
where the first term is the total revenue of the manufacturer, the second term is the manufacturing cost of the manufacturer, the third term is the cost of buying component a 3 from the spot market, the fourth term is the cost of supplier S 2 producing component a 2 , the fifth term is the buy-back cost and the last term is the holding cost.
Consequently, the expected profit function of the manufacturer is given by:
E [ Π M b ] = E [ ( 1 - p ) Π M N + p Π M D ] = E [ ( 1 - p ) ( w m Q - c m Q - w 1 Q - w 2 Q - b ( Q - x ) + - h ( Q - x ) + ) + p ( w m Q - c m Q - w s Q - w 2 Q - b ( Q - β x ) + - h ( Q - β x ) + ) ] = ( 1 - p ) ( w m - c m - w 1 - w 2 ) Q - ( 1 - p ) ( b + h ) 0 Q ( Q - x ) f ( x ) d x + p ( w m - c m - w s - w 2 ) Q - p ( b + h ) 0 Q β ( Q - β x ) f ( x ) d x
Set Q = Q b ; we then obtain the maximal expected profit of the manufacturer as:
E [ Π M b * ] = ( 1 - p ) ( w m - c m - w 1 - w 2 ) Q b - ( 1 - p ) ( b + h ) 0 Q b ( Q b - x ) f ( x ) d x + p ( w m - c m - w s - w 2 ) Q b - p ( b + h ) 0 Q b β ( Q b - β x ) f ( x ) d x
To make each member maximize their own profit while coordinating the supply chain, we can encourage the retailer to order the same amount as the centralized decision-making, namely, Q b = Q c . Combining Equations (2) and (7), we have:
p ( s u + c - b ) F ( Q b β ) + ( 1 - p ) ( s + c - b ) F ( Q b ) = p ( s u - s ) + ( s + c - w m ) p ( s u + c + h ) F ( Q c β ) + ( 1 - p ) ( s + c + h ) F ( Q c ) = p ( s u - s + c 1 - c s - w ) + ( s + c - c m - c 1 - c 2 ) Q b = Q c
or, equivalently,
p ( s u + c - b ) F ( Q b β ) + ( 1 - p ) ( s + c - b ) F ( Q b ) - p ( s u - s ) - ( s + c - w m ) = p ( s u + c + h ) F ( Q c β ) + ( 1 - p ) ( s + c + h ) F ( Q c ) - p ( s u - s + c 1 - c s - w ) - ( s + c - c m - c 1 - c 2 ) Q b = Q c
From Equation (8), we obtain:
b * = p ( c 1 - c s - w ) + ( w m - c m - c 1 - c 2 ) p F ( Q c β ) + ( 1 - p ) F ( Q c ) - h
we then have the following proposition.
Proposition 5. 
The decentralized supply chain can be coordinated by buy-back contracts, only if the buy-back parameter b satisfies Equation (9).
Proposition 5 presents a method to coordinate the decentralized supply chain channel through choosing a suitable buy-back parameter.

7. Numerical Examples

In this section, we present some numerical examples to gain further insights. We assume that the final demand faced by the retailer for the products A and A u is uniformly distributed over the interval ( 50 , 150 ) . In our numerical study, the basic parameter values are given as: s = 16 , s u = 19 , w m = 13 , h = 2 , w = 1 , c = 0 . 5 , c m = 2 , w 1 = 3 . 4 , w 2 = 4 , w s = 5 , c 1 = 2 , c 2 = 3 , c s = 3 . 5 , p { 0 . 2 , 0 . 3 , 0 . 5 } , β { 0 . 60 , 0 . 70 , 0 . 85 } . Demand has a mean of μ X = 100 .
For the model under the centralized decision-making, the optimal order quantity of the retailer, Q c , and the optimal integrated performance, E [ π c * ] , are given in Table 2. Table 2 reveals that an increase in the probability of the supply disruption damages the performance of the supply chain under centralized decision-making. As expected, the higher the market share, β, is, the more integrated the performance, E [ π c * ] , is.
Table 3 shows the optimal order quantity, Q w , each member’s maximal profit and the total profits, E [ π w * ] , of the supply chain based on wholesale price contracts under decentralized decision-making. As the probability of disruption increases, both the order quantity of the retailer and the total profit of the supply chain will decrease. As expected, a higher p reduces the expected profit of the manufacturer and supplier S i ( i = 1 , 2 ) , while positively influencing the retailer’s and spot-market’s profit.
Table 4 represents the optimal buy-back parameter, b * , the optimal order quantity, Q b , the maximal profit of each member and the maximal channel profits, E [ π b * ] , of the supply chain based on buy-back contracts under decentralized decision-making. As shown above, the higher the probability of disruption is, the less buy-back parameter b * and the total profit of the supply chain are.
From Table 2, Table 3 and Table 4, we find that the total profit of the supply chain under buy-back contracts can reach the integrated performance of the centralized decision-making through choosing a suitable buy-back parameter, b * . Namely, buy-back contracts can efficiently coordinate the decentralized supply chain.
Denote the retailer’s maximal profit, the manufacturer’s, the spot market’s, and the maximal profit of the supplier S i ( i = 1 , 2 ) by R, M, SM and Si, respectively. Figure 2, Figure 3 and Figure 4 compare the maximal profit of each member under wholesale price contracts with that under buy-back contracts in the decentralized supply chain when p = 0 . 2 , p = 0 . 3 , p = 0 . 5 , respectively. We find that coordination can enhance each member’s profit, except the manufacturer’s. As the probability of substituting product A u for product A increases, the maximal profit of each member increases in the sense of both wholesale price contracts and buy-back contracts.
Denote the maximal total channel profits of the centralized supply chain, that of the decentralized system under wholesale price contracts and that of the decentralized system under buy-back contracts by CSC, WPC and BBC, respectively. Figure 5 shows that the buy-back contracts can coordinate the decentralized supply chain more effectively than the wholesale price contracts when the supply of component a 1 is disrupted, and the total channel profits under the decentralized decision can recover to the level of the centralized decision under the buy-back contracts.

8. Conclusions

This paper investigates the inventory decision of a retailer and the optimal contract in a multi-echelon supply chain in terms of both supply disruption and stochastic demand based on substitute products. We first obtained the optimal quantity of the supply chain under centralized decision-making. Then, we analyzed the corresponding profit function model under the decentralized decision in the case of wholesale price contracts and buy-back contracts, we found that the decentralized supply chain can be coordinated by buy-back contracts rather than by wholesale price contracts and then drew the conclusion that a properly-designed buy-back policy is able to efficiently coordinate the decentralized supply chain by comparing with the channel total profit under the centralized decision. In fact, we present a more effective method to make the channel total profit under the decentralized decision return to the level of that under centralized decision-making.
Our study is constrained by some assumptions and conditions, such as a single period, a single retailer, a single manufacturer, no stochastic supply, etc. Future research can be extended by relaxing or changing some assumptions and conditions made in this paper. For example,
(1)
considering the optimal order quantity of the retailer under both stochastic demand and supply;
(2)
giving a more detailed description and quantitative analysis for the influence of substitute products on the performance of the supply chain;
(3)
considering a multi-period supply chain model based on both stochastic demand and supply.
All of the questions above may be worthwhile to derive theoretical results.

Acknowledgments

The authors are indebted to the anonymous referees for insightful comments and suggestions, which have greatly improved the presentation of this manuscript and for bringing our attention to recent publications in the relevant literature. This article was supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (71471148) and the Natural Science Foundation of Gansu, China (1104GKCA030).

Author Contributions

All three authors contributed to the scientific study and writing. Rongfang Yan is the principal investigator of this work. He conceived the idea of this paper and wrote the manuscript; Bin Lu and Jianjun Wu contributed to mathematical modeling work and language editing in the manuscript . All authors have read and approved the final manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Proof of Proposition 2. 
We can rewrite Equation (4) as:
E [ Π R w ] = p ( s u + h + c ) 0 Q β ( β x - Q ) f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) 0 Q ( x - Q ) f ( x ) d x + p ( s u - s ) Q + ( s + c - w m ) Q - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p )
Thus,
d E [ Π R w ] d Q = - p ( s u + h + c ) 0 Q β f ( x ) d x - ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) 0 Q f ( x ) d x + p ( s u - s ) + ( s + c - w m )
Note that:
d 2 E [ Π R w ] d Q 2 = - p ( s u + h + c ) f ( Q β ) 1 β - ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) f ( Q ) 0
Consequently, E [ Π R w ] is concave in Q. The unique optimum should satisfy the first order conditions and, hence, complete the proof. ☐
Proof of Proposition 5. 
Under buy-back contracts, the channel total profit of the decentralized supply chain is given by:
E [ Π b * ] = E [ Π R b * ] + E [ Π M b * ] + E [ Π S 1 b * ] + E [ Π S 2 b * ] + E [ Π S M b * ]
Now, set Q b = Q c ; we have:
E [ Π b * ] = { p ( s u + c - b ) 0 Q c β β x f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( s + c - b ) 0 Q c x f ( x ) d x - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p ) } + { ( 1 - p ) ( w m - c m - w 1 - w 2 ) Q c - ( 1 - p ) ( b + h ) 0 Q c ( Q c - x ) f ( x ) d x + p ( w m - c m - w s - w 2 ) Q c - p ( b + h ) 0 Q c β ( Q c - β x ) f ( x ) d x } + { ( 1 - p ) ( w 1 - c 1 ) Q c - p w Q c } + { ( w 2 - c 2 ) Q c } + { p ( w s - c s ) Q c } = p { ( ( s u + c + h ) 0 Q c β β x f ( x ) d x - ( b + h ) 0 Q c β Q c f ( x ) d x + ( c 1 - c s - w ) Q c } + ( 1 - p ) { ( s + c + h ) 0 Q c x f ( x ) d x - ( b + h ) 0 Q c Q c f ( x ) d x } + ( w m - c m - c 1 - c 2 ) Q c - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p )
Note that:
b * = p ( c 1 - c s - w ) + ( w m - c m - c 1 - c 2 ) p F ( Q c β ) + ( 1 - p ) F ( Q c ) - h
or equivalently,
p ( b + h ) 0 Q c β f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( b + h ) 0 Q c f ( x ) d x = p ( c 1 - c s - w ) + ( w m - c m - c 1 - c 2 )
Substituting Equation (A3) into Equation (A2), we have:
E [ Π c * ] = p ( s u + h + c ) 0 Q c β β x f ( x ) d x + ( 1 - p ) ( s + h + c ) 0 Q c x f ( x ) d x - c μ X ( β p + 1 - p )
Comparing Equations (A4) and (3), we find that: E [ Π b * ] = E [ Π c * ] . This shows that the buy-back contracts can coordinate the decentralized supply chain, if b = b * , and, hence, complete the proof. ☐

References

  1. Li, Y.; Zhen, X.; Qi, X.; Cai, G. Penalty and financial assistance in a supply chain with supply disruption. Omega 2016, 61, 167–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Kihyun, P.; Hokey, M.; Soonhong, M. Inter-relationship among risk taking propensity, supply chain security practices, and supply chain disruption occurrence. J. Purch. Suppl. Manag. 2016, 22, 120–130. [Google Scholar]
  3. Chen, K.; Shen, J.; Feng, M. Disruptions management of a supply chain under strategic subsidy policy for the demand-stimulating inventory. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2014, 76, 169–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Liu, Y.; Li, M. On supply chain coordination policy under elastic demand. Ind. Eng. J. 2003, 6, 31–34. [Google Scholar]
  5. Shin, H.; Benton, W.C. A quantity discount approach to supply chain coordination. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2007, 180, 601–616. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Zhou, Y. A comparison of different quantity discount pricing policies in a two-echelon channel with stochastic and asymmetric demand information. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2007, 181, 686–703. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Arcelus, F.J.; Kumar, S.; Srinivasan, G. Evaluating manufacturers’ buy-back policies in a single-period two-echelon framework under price-dependent and stochastic demand. Omega 2008, 36, 808–824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Doǧan, A.S. Inventory and pricing decisions in a single-period problem involving risky supply. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2008, 116, 115–128. [Google Scholar] [Green Version]
  9. Qi, L.; Shen, Z.M.; Snyder, L.V. A continuous-review inventory model with disruptions at both supplier and retailer. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2009, 18, 516–532. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Hou, J.; Zeng, A.Z.; Zhao, L. Coordination with a backup supplier through buy-back contract under supply disruption. Transp. Res. Part E 2010, 46, 881–895. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Sargut, F.Z.; Qi, L. Analysis of a two-party supply chain with random disruptions. Oper. Res. Lett. 2012, 40, 114–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. He, B.; Huang, H.; Yuan, K. The comparison of two procurement strategies in the presence of supply disruption. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2015, 85, 296–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Lou, S.; Wu, Y.; Lü, W. Study on inventory control under stochastic disruptions. Acta Autom. Sin. 2010, 36, 999–1006. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Zhang, G.; Xie, J. Research on an inventory control model with supply disruptions. Syst. Eng. Theory Pract. 2006, 12, 69–77. [Google Scholar]
  15. He, Y.; Zhao, X. Coordination in multi-echelon supply chain under supply and demand uncertainty. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 139, 106–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Shao, X. Demand-side reactive strategies for supply disruptions in a multiple-product system. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 136, 241–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Arcelus, F.; Kumar, S.; Srinivasan, G. Evaluating manufacturers’ buy-back policies in a single-period two-echelon framework under price dependent and stochastic demand. Omega 2008, 36, 808–824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Hu, F.; Lim, C.C.; Lu, Z. Coordination of supply chains with a flexible ordering policy under yield and demand uncertainty. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2013, 146, 686–693. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Bassok, Y.; Snupindi, R.; Akella, R. Single-period multi-product inventory models with substitution. Oper. Res. 1999, 4, 632–642. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Balakrishnan, A.; Geunes, J. Requirements planning with substitutions: exploiting bill-of-materials flexibility in production planning. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2000, 2, 166–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Wang, K.; Zhao, Y.; Cheng, Y.; Choi, T.M. Cooperation or competition?Channel choice for a remanufacturing fashion supply chain with government subsidy. Sustainability 2014, 6, 7292–7310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Pasternack, B.A. Optimal pricing and returns policies for perishable commodities. Mark. Sci. 1985, 8, 166–176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Tsay, A.A.; Nahmias, S.; Afrawal, N. Modeling supply chain contracts: A review. In Quantitative Models for Supply Chain Management; Tayur, S., Ganeshan, R., Magazine, M., Eds.; Kluwer Academic Publishers: Dordrecht, The Netherland, 1999; pp. 300–336. [Google Scholar]
  24. Lariviere, M.A. Supply chain contracting and coordination with stochastic demand. In Quantitative Models for Supply Chain Management; Kluwer Academic Publishers: Bosten, MA, USA, 1999; pp. 233–268. [Google Scholar]
  25. Lariviere, M.A.; Porteus, E. Selling to the newsvendor: An analysis of price-only contracts. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2001, 3, 293–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Padmanabhan, V.; Png, I. Manufactures’ returns policy and retail competition. Mark. Sci. 1997, 16, 81–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Yao, D.; Yue, X.; Wang, X.; Liu, J. The impact of information sharing on a return policy with the addition of a direct channel. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2005, 97, 196–209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Yu, H.; Chen, J.; Yu, G. Managing wholesale price contract in the supply chain under disruptions. Syst. Eng. Theory Pract. 2005, 26, 33–41. [Google Scholar]
  29. Yang, D.; Choi, T.M.; Xiao, T.; Cheng, T. Coordinating a two-supplier and one-retailer supply chain with forecast updating. Automatica 2011, 47, 1317–1329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Christos, Z.; George, T. Impact of uncertainty in the quality of returns on the profitability of a single-period refurbishing operation. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2007, 182, 205–225. [Google Scholar]
  31. Anastasios, X.; Dimitrios, V.; Eleftherios, I. Optimal newsvendor policies for dual-sourcing supply chains: A disruption risk management framework. Comput. Oper. Res. 2012, 39, 350–357. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Model structures to be studied without the supply disruption.
Figure 1. Model structures to be studied without the supply disruption.
Sustainability 08 00676 g001
Figure 2. Comparison of the profits in two cases: (a) wholesale price; and (b) buy-back contract (p = 0.2).
Figure 2. Comparison of the profits in two cases: (a) wholesale price; and (b) buy-back contract (p = 0.2).
Sustainability 08 00676 g002aSustainability 08 00676 g002b
Figure 3. Comparison of the profits in two cases: (a) wholesale price; and (b) buy-back contract (p = 0.3).
Figure 3. Comparison of the profits in two cases: (a) wholesale price; and (b) buy-back contract (p = 0.3).
Sustainability 08 00676 g003
Figure 4. Comparison of the profits in two cases: (a) wholesale price; and (b) buy-back contract (p = 0.5).
Figure 4. Comparison of the profits in two cases: (a) wholesale price; and (b) buy-back contract (p = 0.5).
Sustainability 08 00676 g004
Figure 5. Comparison of the channel profit in three case of the centralized supply chain (CSC), the wholesale price contract (WPC) and the buy-back contract (BBC) when β = 0 . 6 .
Figure 5. Comparison of the channel profit in three case of the centralized supply chain (CSC), the wholesale price contract (WPC) and the buy-back contract (BBC) when β = 0 . 6 .
Sustainability 08 00676 g005
Table 1. Notes for the symbols.
Table 1. Notes for the symbols.
Decision variables
QQuantity of product A or A u ordered by the retailer
Parameters
hThe unit holding cost
cThe unit shortage cost
wThe unit lost cost of supplier S 1
sThe unit retail price of product A
s u The unit retail price of product A u
w m The unit wholesale price of A and A u determined by the manufacturer
w i The unit wholesale price of component a i offered by supplier S i
c m The unit manufacturing cost of manufacturer
bthe buy-back price for each unit of unsold products
c i The unit product cost of supplier S i
w s The unit wholesale price of component a 3 offered by the spot market
c s The unit running cost of spot market
pThe probability of supply disruption of component a 1
βThe probability of substituting A u for A
XThe random market demands of product A
μ X The mean demand
Table 2. Total profit of the centralized system.
Table 2. Total profit of the centralized system.
pβ Q c E [ π c * ]
0 . 2 0 . 70 91 . 44 605 . 92
0 . 85 96 . 43 644 . 13
0 . 3 0 . 70 87 . 3 580 . 79
0 . 85 93 . 97 628 . 64
0 . 5 0 . 70 80 . 26 540 . 37
0 . 85 89 . 56 602 . 09
Table 3. Maximal profit of supply chain members with wholesale price contracts.
Table 3. Maximal profit of supply chain members with wholesale price contracts.
pβ Q w E [ π R w * ] E [ π M w * ] E [ π S 1 w * ] E [ π S 2 w * ] E [ π S M w * ] E [ π w * ]
0 . 2 0 . 70 65 . 18 175 . 24 234 . 65 59 . 87 65 . 18 19 . 55 554 . 59
0 . 85 68 . 73 189 . 86 247 . 43 63 . 23 68 . 73 20 . 62 589 . 87
0 . 3 0 . 70 63 . 61 184 . 6 216 . 27 43 . 25 63 . 61 28 . 62 536 . 35
0 . 85 68 . 65 205 . 81 233 . 41 46 . 68 68 . 65 30 . 89 585 . 44
0 . 5 0 . 70 60 . 96 205 . 03 182 . 88 12 . 19 60 . 96 45 . 72 506 . 78
0 . 85 68 . 5 237 . 64 205 . 5 13 . 7 68 . 5 51 . 37 576 . 72
Table 4. Maximal profit of supply chain members with buy-back contracts.
Table 4. Maximal profit of supply chain members with buy-back contracts.
pβ b * Q b E [ π R b * ] E [ π M b * ] E [ π S 1 b * ] E [ π S 2 b * ] E [ π S M b * ] E [ π b * ]
0 . 2 0 . 70 9 . 16 91 . 44 230 . 44 172 . 49 84 . 12 91 . 44 27 . 43 605 . 92
0 . 85 9 . 04 96 . 43 246 . 63 183 . 42 88 . 72 96 . 43 28 . 93 644 . 13
0 . 3 0 . 70 8 . 82 87 . 3 238 . 59 156 . 26 59 . 36 87 . 3 39 . 28 580 . 79
0 . 85 8 . 73 93 . 97 258 . 17 170 . 41 63 . 8 93 . 97 42 . 29 628 . 64
0 . 5 0 . 70 8 80 . 26 255 . 52 128 . 34 16 . 05 80 . 26 60 . 2 540 . 37
0 . 85 8 89 . 56 281 . 15 146 . 3 17 . 91 89 . 56 67 . 17 602 . 09

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Yan, R.; Lu, B.; Wu, J. Contract Coordination Strategy of Supply Chain with Substitution under Supply Disruption and Stochastic Demand. Sustainability 2016, 8, 676. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su8070676

AMA Style

Yan R, Lu B, Wu J. Contract Coordination Strategy of Supply Chain with Substitution under Supply Disruption and Stochastic Demand. Sustainability. 2016; 8(7):676. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su8070676

Chicago/Turabian Style

Yan, Rongfang, Bin Lu, and Jianjun Wu. 2016. "Contract Coordination Strategy of Supply Chain with Substitution under Supply Disruption and Stochastic Demand" Sustainability 8, no. 7: 676. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/su8070676

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop