Next Article in Journal
Classifying a Lending Portfolio of Loans with Dynamic Updates via a Machine Learning Technique
Next Article in Special Issue
Pathwise Convergent Approximation for the Fractional SDEs
Previous Article in Journal
Defocused Image Deep Learning Designed for Wavefront Reconstruction in Tomographic Pupil Image Sensors
Previous Article in Special Issue
A Fast-Pivoting Algorithm for Whittle’s Restless Bandit Index
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Positive Solutions of the Fractional SDEs with Non-Lipschitz Diffusion Coefficient

by
Kęstutis Kubilius
and
Aidas Medžiūnas
*
Faculty of Mathematics and Informatics, Vilnius University, Akademijos g. 4, 08412 Vilnius, Lithuania
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Submission received: 23 November 2020 / Revised: 14 December 2020 / Accepted: 18 December 2020 / Published: 23 December 2020
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Applied Probability)

Abstract

:
We study a class of fractional stochastic differential equations (FSDEs) with coefficients that may not satisfy the linear growth condition and non-Lipschitz diffusion coefficient. Using the Lamperti transform, we obtain conditions for positivity of solutions of such equations. We show that the trajectories of the fractional CKLS model with β > 1 are not necessarily positive. We obtain the almost sure convergence rate of the backward Euler approximation scheme for solutions of the considered SDEs. We also obtain a strongly consistent and asymptotically normal estimator of the Hurst index H > 1 / 2 for positive solutions of FSDEs.

1. Introduction

The models defined by stochastic differential equations (SDEs)
X t = x 0 + 0 t g ( X s ) d s +   0 t X s β d B s , β 1 / 2 , β 1 ,
where B is a standard Brownian motion, g is a continuous function on ( 0 , ) , x 0 > 0 is nonrandom initial value, and σ > 0 is a constant, include several well-known models such as Chan–Karolyi–Longstaff–Sanders (CKLS), Cox–Ingersoll–Ross (CIR), Ait–Sahalia (AS), Cox–Ingersoll–Ross variable-rate (CIR VR), and others used in many financial applications [1,2,3,4,5,6]. The positivity is a desirable property for many financial models, such as option pricing, stochastic volatility, and interest rate models. Thus, it is important to find conditions under which the solutions to Equation (1) are positive. Preservation of positivity is a desirable modelling property, and in many cases the non-negativity of numerical approximations is needed for the scheme to be well defined. Therefore, many numerical methods have been developed to preserve the positivity of the approximate solution in the case of the positive true solution.
For an SDE to have a unique global solution (i.e., with no explosion in a finite time) for any given initial value, the coefficients of the equation are in general required to satisfy the linear growth and local Lipschitz conditions. These conditions are not satisfied in the models mentioned. The existence of positive solutions of SDEs corresponding to these models and implicit numerical schemes preserving the positivity were studied in [1,2,3,4,5,6].
An important research area in financial mathematics is the long memory phenomenon in financial data. Hence, since fractional Brownian motion (fBm) B H introduces a memory element, there is much attention in recent years to models with fBm. Consider the FSDEs
X t = x 0 + 0 t g ( X s ) d s + σ 0 t X s β d B s H , β 1 / 2 , β 1 ,
with H ( 1 / 2 , 1 ) . The stochastic integral in Equation (2) is a pathwise Riemann–Stieltjes integral, but SDE (2) cannot be treated directly since the functions k ( x ) = x β , β 1 / 2 , β 1 , do not satisfy the usual Lipschitz conditions.
For fractional CIR, CKLS, and AS models, the existence of a unique positive solution of Equation (2) was obtained in [7,8,9,10,11,12,13,14]. The proof can be provided in several ways. One approach is based on the consideration of the conditions under which the equation
Y t = y 0 + 0 t h ( s , Y s ) d s + B t H , H ( 1 / 2 , 1 ) ,
admits a unique positive solution, where h ( t , x ) is a locally Lipschitz function with respect to the space variable x ( 0 , ) . This approach was used in [7,8,9,11,14], where the inverse Lamperti transform was used to obtain conditions under which Equation (1) admits a unique positive solution for fractional CIR, CKLS, and AS models. Unfortunately, we cannot apply the proof of positivity of the solution of (3) given in [14] (e.g., it is not applicable to the AS model).
Marie [10] used the rough-path approach to find the existence of a unique positive solution of the fractional CKLS model.
A simulation of the fractional CIR process was given in [11] by using the Euler approximation. In [8,14] an almost sure strongly convergent approximation of the considered SDE solution is constructed using the backward Euler scheme, which is positivity preserving.
In this paper, we consider the SDE
Y t = y 0 + ( β 1 ) 0 t h ( Y s ) d s ( β 1 ) σ B t H , β > 1 ,
where y 0 is a constant. This type of equation is obtained after the Lamperti transformation of the FSDE (2). The purpose of the paper is finding sufficiently simple conditions when the solution of (4) for β > 1 and H ( 1 / 2 , 1 ) is positive. Moreover, using the backward Euler scheme, which preserves the positivity for (4), we obtain an almost sure convergence rate for X. Since the problem of the statistical estimation of the long-memory parameter H is of great importance, we construct an estimate of the Hurst index H ( 1 / 2 , 1 ) in the same way as for the diffusion coefficient satisfying the usual Lipschitz conditions (see [15,16]). This can be done since the solution of Equation (2) is positive. More results on parameter estimations for the FSDEs can be found in the book [17].
The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present the main results of the paper. In Section 3, we prove the main auxiliary result on the existence and uniqueness of a positive solution for SDE (4). Section 4 contains proofs of the main theorems. In Section 5, we consider fractional CKLS and AS models as examples. Finally, in Appendix A, we recall the Love–Young inequality, the chain rule for Hölder-continuous functions, and some results for fBm.

2. Main Results

We are interested in conditions under which the SDE
X t = x 0 + 0 t X s β f ( X s 1 β ) d s + σ 0 t X s β d B s H , β > 1 ,   H ( 1 / 2 , 1 ) ,
has a unique positive solution. The stochastic integral in Equation (5) is a pathwise Riemann–Stieltjes integral.
To state our main results, we assume that the following conditions on the function f in (5) are satisfied:
( C 1 ) f is a locally Lipschitz on ( 0 , + ) ;
( C 2 ) There exist constants a > 0 and α 0 such that
f ^ ( x ) : = f ( x ) a x 1 + α
for all sufficiently small x ( 0 , ) ;
( C 3 ) The function f ^ ( x ) satisfies the one-sided Lipschitz condition, that is, there exists a constant K R such that
( x y ) ( f ^ ( x ) f ^ ( y ) ) K ( x y ) 2
for all x , y ( 0 , + ) .
Theorem 1. 
If a function f satisfies conditions ( C 1 ) ( C 3 ) , then Equation (5) is well defined and has a unique positive solution X C γ ( [ 0 , T ] ) of order γ ( 1 2 , H ) for H ( 1 2 , 1 ) , where C γ ( [ 0 , T ] ) denotes the space of Hölder-continuous functions of order γ > 0 on [ 0 , T ] .
Consider the SDE
Y t = y 0 + ( β 1 ) 0 t f ^ ( Y s ) d s ( β 1 ) σ B t H , y 0 = x 0 1 β , t 0 , H ( 1 2 , 1 ) .
A strong approximation of the SDE that has locally Lipschitz drift for H ( 1 2 , 1 ) is constructed by applying the backward Euler scheme in [14] (see also [1] for H = 1 2 ). By using the backward Euler scheme, which preserves positivity for (6), we obtain an almost sure convergence rate for X.
A sequence of uniform partitions of the interval [ 0 , T ] we denote by π = { t k n = k n T , 1 k n } and let and h = t k n t k 1 n , 1 k n . We introduce the backward Euler approximation scheme for Y
Y n , k + 1 = Y n , k + ( β 1 ) f ^ ( Y n , k + 1 ) h σ ( β 1 ) B t k + 1 n H B t k n H , Y n , 0 = y 0 , 0 k n 1 .
The following assumption is needed for the positivity of the backward Euler approximation scheme to be preserved:
( C 4 ) Let F ^ ( x ) = x ( β 1 ) f ^ ( x ) h on ( 0 , ) , where the function f ^ ( x ) satisfies condition ( C 3 ) . There exists h 0 > 0 such that lim x + F ^ ( x ) = + and lim x 0 + F ^ ( x ) = for 0 < h < h 0 .
Remark 1. 
Please note that under condition ( C 3 ) , the function F ^ ( x ) is strictly monotone on ( 0 , ) for small h. This follows from ( C 3 ) and the inequality
( x y ) ( F ^ ( x ) F ^ ( y ) ) = ( x y ) 2 ( β 1 ) ( x y ) ( f ^ ( x ) f ^ ( y ) ) h ( 1 K + ( β 1 ) h ) ( x y ) 2 > 0 ,
where K + = max { 0 , K } . Thus, from the condition ( C 4 ) it follows that for each b R , the equation F ( x ) = b has a unique positive solution for 0 < h < h 0 . As a result, we see that the positivity is preserved by the backward Euler approximation scheme.
For the simplicity of notation, we introduce the symbol O ω . Let ( Z n ) be a sequence of r.v.s, let ς be an a.s. nonnegative r.v., and let ( a n ) ( 0 , ) be a vanishing sequence. Then Z n = O ω ( a n ) means that | Z n | ς · a n for all n. In particular, Z n = O ω ( 1 ) means that the sequence ( Z n ) is a.s. bounded.
Theorem 2. 
Suppose that the function f in (5) is continuously differentiable on ( 0 , + ) and satisfies condition ( C 2 ) and that there exists a constant K R such that the derivative is bounded above by K, that is, f ( x ) K . If the sequence of uniform partitions π of the interval [ 0 , T ] is such that h < h 0 , then for all T > 0 and H ( 1 2 , 1 ) ,
sup 0 t T | Y t Y t n | = O ω ( n H ln n ) ,
where
Y t n = Y n , k + t t k n h Y n , k + 1 Y n , k , t ( t k n , t k + 1 n ] ,   k = 0 , , n 1 , Y n , 0 n = y 0 .
Moreover,
sup 0 t T X t Y t n 1 / ( β 1 ) = O ω n H ln n f o r β ( 1 , 2 ] , O ω ( n H ln n ) 1 / ( β 1 ) f o r β > 2 ,
where X is the solution of Equation (5).
For positive solutions of Equation (5), we construct a strongly consistent and asymptotically normal estimator of the Hurst parameter H from discrete observations of a single sample path.
For a real-valued process X = { X t , t [ 0 , T ] } , we define the second order increments along uniform partitions as
Δ n , k ( 2 ) X = X t k + 1 n 2 X t k n + X t k 1 n , 1 k n 1 .
Theorem 3. 
Let X be a unique positive solution of SDE (5) with H ( 1 2 , 1 ) . Then
H ^ n = H + O ω ln n n 1 / 2
and
2 ln 2 n ( H ^ n H ) d N ( 0 , σ H 2 )
with known variance σ H 2 defined in Appendix, where
H ^ n = 1 2 1 2 ln 2 ln V ˜ 2 n , T ( 2 ) X V ˜ n , T ( 2 ) X , V ˜ n , T ( 2 ) X = k = 1 n 1 Δ n , k ( 2 ) X X t k n β 2 .

3. Auxiliary Results

As mentioned in Introduction, we are interested in conditions under which the SDE (6) has a unique positive solution.
Proposition 1. 
Suppose that a function f satisfies conditions ( C 1 ) ( C 3 ) . If y 0 > 0 , k 1 > 0 , and k 2 R , then there exists a unique positive solution of Equation (6) such that Y C γ ( [ 0 , T ] ) , T > 0 , where γ ( 1 2 , H ) and H ( 1 2 , 1 ) .
We easily to see that the same proof as in Proposition 1 [8] remains valid for Proposition 1.
Applying Proposition 1 to the fractional AS model and Heston-3/2 volatility model, we obtain that the trajectories of these models are positive (see Section 5). Our proof scheme gives no answer about the behavior of the trajectories of the CKLS model
X t = x 0 + 0 t ( a 1 a 2 X s ) d s + σ 0 t X s β d B s H , β > 1 , H ( 1 2 , 1 ) ,
with the initial value x 0 > 0 and deterministic constants a 1 > 0 , a 2 R , and σ > 0 .
Now we will explain why we cannot give an answer about the behavior of the trajectories of the CKLS model. Consider the SDE
Y t = y 0 + ( β 1 ) 0 t ( a 2 Y s a 1 Y s β / ( β 1 ) ) d s ( β 1 ) σ B t H , H ( 1 2 , 1 ) .
Suppose that the solution of the SDE (11) is positive. Then by applying the chain rule (see Appendix A.2) and the inverse Lamperti transform X t = Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) we can prove that X is a positive solution of (10).
Unfortunately, it is easy to see that the function f ^ ( x ) = a 2 x a 1 x β / ( β 1 ) does not satisfy condition ( C 2 ) . So, we cannot apply Proposition 1 and say anything about the positivity of the solution of (11).
Computer modelling using Wolfram Mathematica shows that the trajectories of the process Y may have negative values for y 0 > 0 (see Figure 1).
To investigate the probability of reaching the negative values by the process Y when t [ 0 , 1 ] , we simulate the “exact” solution by using the backward Euler approximation scheme for step size h = 10 3 and repeat this process 10 3 times counting the trajectories with negative values. We observe that the solution has a higher probability to reach the negative values for small initial values Y 0 and that for large enough values of Y 0 , this probability tends to zero. Additionally, the probability increases for greater values of the parameters σ , β (see Figure 2b and Figure 3) and decreases for greater values of the parameters H , a 2 (see Figure 2a and Figure 4b). The influence of a 1 on the probability (see Figure 4a) is not noticeable in comparison with other parameters.
Thus, we can only state that Equation (10) has a solution X t = Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) until the moment at which Y becomes zero. On the other hand, we do know that the CKLS model driven by a standard Brownian motion (see [6]) with β > 1 and the fractional CKLS model with 1 / 2 β < 1 (see [8]) have positive solutions.

4. Proofs

The main tool for proving Theorem 1 is Proposition 1.
Proof of Theorem 1. 
Set X t = Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) and x 0 = y 0 1 / ( β 1 ) , where Y is a solution of Equation (6). Since the process Y is positive and continuous, for s , t [ 0 , T ] , we get
| Y t β / ( β 1 ) Y s β / ( β 1 ) | = | Y t β / ( β 1 ) Y s β / ( β 1 ) | Y t β / ( β 1 ) Y s β / ( β 1 ) 1 inf 0 t T Y t 2 β / ( β 1 ) β β 1 sup 0 t T Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) · | Y t Y s | .
Thus, X s β is a Hölder-continuous process up to the order γ ( 1 2 , H ) on [ 0 , T ] . The process X t = Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) is the solution of Equation (5). Indeed, by chain rule we obtain
X t = Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) = Y 0 1 / ( β 1 ) 1 β 1 0 t Y s β / ( β 1 ) d Y s = y 0 1 / ( β 1 ) β 1 β 1 0 t Y s β / ( β 1 ) f ^ ( Y s ) d s + σ ( β 1 ) β 1 0 t Y s β / ( β 1 ) d B s H = x 0 + 0 t g ( X s ) d s + σ 0 t X s β d B s H .
Proof of Theorem 2. 
We repeat the outlines of the proof of Theorem 3 in [8]. Please note that under the conditions of the theorem, conditions ( C 1 ) ( C 3 ) are satisfied. Thus, there exists a unique positive solution of SDE (6).
By the definition of Y n , for any t ( t k n , t k + 1 n ] , we have
Y t Y t n = Y t t t k n h Y n , k + 1 t k + 1 n t h Y n , k = t k n t h ( β 1 ) t t k + 1 n f ^ ( Y s ) d s σ B t k + 1 n H B t H + t k + 1 n t h ( β 1 ) t k n t f ^ ( Y s ) d s σ B t H B t k n H + t t k n h Y t k + 1 n Y n , k + 1 + t k + 1 n t h Y t k n Y k .
Since the process Y is positive and continuous, from (A5) it follows that
| Y t Y s | ( β 1 ) s t | f ^ ( Y u ) | d u + ( β 1 ) σ | B t H B s H | ( β 1 ) ( t s ) sup 0 u T | f ^ ( Y u ) | + ( β 1 ) K ω | t s | H | ln | t s | | = O ω | t s | H | ln | t s | | ,
and the asymptotic behavior of the first two terms is O ω ( n H ln n ) . Thus, it remains to obtain the asymptotics of the last two terms.
Please note that
Y t k + 1 n Y n , k + 1 = Y t k n Y n , k + ( β 1 ) t k n t k + 1 n f ^ ( Y s ) f ^ ( Y n , k + 1 ) d s + ( β 1 ) σ ζ k + 1 ( Y t k + 1 n Y n , k + 1 ) h ,
where ζ k + 1 = f ^ ( Y t k + 1 n + θ ( Y n , k + 1 Y t k + 1 n ) ) , θ ( 0 , 1 ) . Then
Y t k + 1 n Y n , k + 1 = 1 1 ( β 1 ) ζ k + 1 h Y t k n Y n , k + ( β 1 ) t k n t k + 1 n f ^ ( Y s ) f ^ ( Y t k + 1 n ) d s = i = 1 k + 1 I i j = i k + 1 1 ζ j ( β 1 ) h 1 ,
where
I i = ( β 1 ) t i 1 n t i n f ^ ( Y s ) f ^ ( Y t i n ) d s .
Please note that 1 ζ i ( β 1 ) h 1 ( β 1 ) K + h > 0 for h < ( ( β 1 ) K + ) 1 since f ( x ) K , where K + = max { 0 , K } . Applying the inequality ln 1 1 x x 1 x , x < 1 , we get
j = i k + 1 1 ζ j ( β 1 ) h 1 ( 1 ( β 1 ) K + h ) ( k + 1 i ) e n ln 1 1 ( β 1 ) K + h e n ( β 1 ) K + h 1 ( β 1 ) K + h e ( β 1 ) K + T 1 ( β 1 ) K + h .
Furthermore,
| t k 1 n t k n f ^ ( Y s ) f ^ ( Y t k n ) d s | T n 1 max 0 t T | f ^ ( Y t ) | max t k 1 n t t k n | Y t Y t k n | = O ω n H ln n .
This finishes the proof of (8).
It remains to prove (9). We will use the well-known inequalities
| x p y p | | x y | p , 0 < p < 1 , | x p y p | < p | x y | ( max { | x | , | y | } ) p 1 , p > 1 .
Since X t = Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) , we have
sup 0 t T | X t Y t n 1 / ( β 1 ) | = sup 0 t T | Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) Y t n 1 / ( β 1 ) | = sup 0 t T | Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) Y t n 1 / ( β 1 ) | Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) Y t n 1 / ( β 1 ) .
Please note that
inf 0 t T Y t n min 0 n Y n , k > 0 .
Thus
sup 0 t T | X t Y ^ t n 1 / ( β 1 ) | sup 0 t T | Y t Y ^ t n | 1 / ( β 1 ) Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) Y ^ t n 1 / ( β 1 ) if β > 2 , sup 0 t T | Y t Y ^ t n | Y t Y ^ t n if β = 2 , 1 β 1 sup 0 t T | Y t Y ^ t n | Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) Y ^ t n 1 / ( β 1 ) × max sup 0 t T | Y t | , sup 0 t T | Y ^ t n | 2 β β 1 if 1 < β < 2 .
From (8) and the finiteness of sup 0 t T | Y t | we have
sup 0 t T | Y ^ t n | sup 0 t T | Y ^ t n Y t | + sup 0 t T | Y t | O ω n H ln n + sup 0 t T | Y t | = O ω ( 1 ) .
This finishes the proof of (9). □
Proof of Theorem 3.
Repeats the proof of Theorem 2 in [8]. It is based on the following lemma. □
Lemma 1. 
Assume that the conditions of Theorem 1 are satisfied and β > 1 . Then
Δ n , i ( 2 ) X = σ X β ( t i n ) Δ n , i ( 2 ) B H + O ω ( n 2 γ ) ,
where γ ( 1 / 2 , H ) .
Proof. 
Let g ( x ) = x β f ( x 1 β ) . Then can we write the second-order increments of the process X as follows:
Δ n , k ( 2 ) X = t k n t k + 1 n g ( X s ) g ( X t k n ) d s t k 1 n t k n g ( X s ) g ( X t k n ) d s + σ t k n t k + 1 n X s β X t k n β d B s H t k 1 n t k n X s β X t k n β d B s H + σ X t k n β Δ n , i ( 2 ) B H .
Applying inequality (12), condition ( C 1 ) , and the fact that Y C γ ( [ 0 , T ] ) , γ ( 1 2 , H ) , we obtain
| g ( X t ) g ( X s ) | = | Y t β / ( β 1 ) f ( Y t ) Y s β / ( β 1 ) f ( Y s ) | | f ( Y t ) | · | Y t β / ( β 1 ) Y s β / ( β 1 ) | + Y s β / ( β 1 ) | f ( Y t ) f ( Y s ) | sup 0 t T | f ( Y t ) | · 1 inf 0 t T Y t 2 β / ( β 1 ) β β 1 sup 0 t T Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) · | Y t Y s | + sup 0 t T Y t β / ( β 1 ) sup 0 t T | f ( Y t ) | · | Y t Y s | = O ω ( n γ ) .
Thus
t k n t k + 1 n | g ( X s ) g ( X t k n ) | d s = O ω ( n 1 γ ) and t i 1 n t i n | g ( X s ) g ( X t k n ) | d s = O ω ( n 1 γ ) .
Moreover, by the Love–Young inequality (see Appendix A.1), (12), and the Hölder continuity of B H we get
t i 1 n t i n X s β X t i n β B s H C γ , γ 1 inf 0 t T Y t 2 β / ( β 1 ) β β 1 sup 0 t T Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) K Y , T G γ , T n 2 γ ,
where K Y , T = sup s , t [ 0 , T ] s t | Y t Y s | | s t | γ < a.s. Thus, the lemma is proved. □

5. Examples

Example 1. 
Ait–Sahalia model. The Ait–Sahalia-type SDE has the form
X t = x 0 + 0 t ( a 1 X s 1 a 2 + a 3 X s a 4 X s r ) d s + σ 0 t X s β d B s H
with the initial value x 0 > 0 and r > 2 β 1 , where H ( 1 2 , 1 ) , β > 1 , and deterministic constants a 1 , a 2 , a 3 , a 4 > 0 and σ > 0 .
By using the Lamperti transformation Y t = X t ( β 1 ) we get
Y t = y 0 ( β 1 ) 0 t f ( Y s ) d s σ ( β 1 ) B t H = y 0 + ( β 1 ) 0 t f ^ ( Y s ) d s ( β 1 ) σ B t H ,
where f ^ ( x ) = f ( x ) and
f ( x ) = a 1 x β + 1 β 1 a 2 x β β 1 + a 3 x a 4 x r β β 1 .
The function f is continuously differentiable on ( 0 , + ) . Condition ( C 2 ) is satisfied since
f ^ ( x ) a 4 2 x r β β 1 = a 4 2 x r β β 1 a 1 x β + 1 β 1 + a 2 x β β 1 a 3 x a s x + 0
with a = a 4 / 2 , α = r β β 1 1 > 0 .
Now we verify condition ( C 3 ) . Please note that
f ^ ( x ) = a 1 β + 1 β 1 x 2 β 1 + a 2 β β 1 x 1 β 1 a 3 a 4 r β β 1 x r 1 β 1 = x r 1 β 1 a 4 r β β 1 + a 1 β + 1 β 1 x 1 + r β 1 a 2 β β 1 x r β 1 a 3 = x 2 β 1 a 1 β + 1 β 1 a 2 β β 1 x 1 β 1 + a 4 r β β 1 x r + 1 β 1 a 3 .
Since the derivative f ^ ( x ) is continuous on ( 0 , ) , lim x 0 + f ^ ( x ) = , and lim x + f ^ ( x ) = , there is a constant K such that f ^ ( x ) K for all x ( 0 , ) .
Now the mean value theorem implies
( x y ) f ^ ( x ) f ^ ( x ) = f ^ ( c ) ( x y ) 2 K ( x y ) 2 ,
where c = x + θ ( y x ) , θ ( 0 , 1 ) . Thus, Equation (14) has a unique positive solution on ( 0 , + ) .
Let us verify condition ( C 4 ) . Please note that
F ^ ( x ) = x ( β 1 ) f ^ ( x ) h = x ( β 1 ) a 1 x β + 1 β 1 + a 2 x β β 1 a 3 x + a 4 x r β β 1 h = ( β 1 ) a 1 x β + 1 β 1 a 2 x β β 1 a 4 x r β β 1 h + 1 + a 3 ( β 1 ) h x
is continuous on ( 0 , ) . It is clear that 1 + a 3 ( β 1 ) h > 0 for any h > 0 and
lim x 0 + F ^ ( x ) = a n d lim x + F ^ ( x ) = + .
Since the function f ^ satisfies condition ( C 3 ) , condition ( C 4 ) is satisfied as well. Therefore, the conditions of Theorem 2 are satisfied.
Example 2. 
Heston-3/2 volatility mode. Consider the SDE
X t = x 0 + 0 t a 1 X s ( a 2 X s ) d s + σ 0 t X s β d B s H
with the initial value x 0 > 0 , where H ( 1 2 , 1 ) , 1 < β < 2 , and deterministic constants a 1 , a 2 , σ > 0 . If β = 3 / 2 , then we call the SDE (16) the fractional Heston- 3 / 2 volatility model.
By using the Lamperti transformation Y t = X t ( β 1 ) we get
Y t = y 0 ( β 1 ) 0 t f ( Y s ) d s σ ( β 1 ) B t H = y 0 + ( β 1 ) 0 t f ^ ( Y s ) d s σ ( β 1 ) B t H ,
where f ^ ( x ) = f ( x ) and
f ( x ) = a 1 a 2 x a 1 x 2 β β 1 .
The function f is continuously differentiable on ( 0 , + ) . Condition ( C 2 ) is satisfied since
f ^ ( x ) a 1 2 x 2 β β 1 = a 1 2 x 2 β β 1 a 1 a 2 x a s x + 0
with a = a 1 / 2 , α = 2 β β 1 1 > 0 . Now we verify condition ( C 3 ) . Please note that
f ^ ( x ) = a 1 a 2 a 1 2 β β 1 x 1 β 1 < a 1 a 2 .
Applying inequality (15), we obtain condition ( C 3 ) . Thus, Equation (16) has a unique positive solution on ( 0 , + ) . From the obtained result it follows that the Heston- 3 / 2 volatility model has a unique positive solution on ( 0 , + ) .
Let us verify condition ( C 4 ) . Please note that
F ^ ( x ) = x ( β 1 ) f ^ ( x ) h = x ( β 1 ) a 1 a 2 x + a 1 x 2 β β 1 h = 1 + a 1 a 2 ( β 1 ) h x ( β 1 ) a 1 x 2 β β 1 h
is continuous on ( 0 , ) . It is clear that 1 + a 3 ( β 1 ) h > 0 for any h > 0 and
lim x 0 + F ^ ( x ) = a n d lim x + F ^ ( x ) = + .
Since the function f ^ satisfies condition ( C 3 ) , condition ( C 4 ) is satisfied as well. Thus the conditions of Theorem 2 are satisfied.

6. Conclusions

In this paper, we gave sufficiently simple conditions under which the solution of SDE
Y t = y 0 ( β 1 ) 0 t f ( Y s ) d s ( β 1 ) σ B t H , β > 1 , H ( 1 / 2 , 1 ) ,
has a unique positive solution. By applying the chain rule and the inverse Lamperti transform X t = Y t 1 / ( β 1 ) , we proved that X is a positive solution of equation
X t = x 0 + 0 t X s β f ( X s 1 β ) d s + σ 0 t X s β d B s H , β > 1 ,
under certain conditions on the function f.
Equation (18) describes models, such as fractional Ait–Sahalia and Heston- 3 / 2 volatility, in which the positivity is important for many financial applications. Usually, we are not aware of an explicit expression for the solution, and therefore we considered computable discrete-time approximations, which can be used in Monte Carlo simulations. To approximate the solution of Equation (17), we used an implicit Euler scheme, which preserves the positivity of the numerical scheme. By applying the inverse Lamperti transform to Y we obtained an approximation scheme for the original SDE (18). Moreover, we obtained the almost sure convergence rate for both processes.
Not all models defined by the stochastic differential Equation (18) necessarily have positive trajectories. The paths of the fractional CKLS model are not necessarily positive, in contrast to the classical CKLS model driven by the standard Brownian motion with β > 1 or fractional CKLS model with 1 / 2 β < 1 .
The statistical estimation of the long-memory parameter H is of great importance, therefore, we constructed its estimate. For the first time, we obtained an estimate of the Hurst index for the solution of Equation (18). Finally, the positivity of solution of (18) allowed us to construct an estimate of the Hurst index, which is not only strongly consistent, but also asymptotically normal.

Author Contributions

Supervision, K.K.; software, A.M.; writing, original draft preparation, K.K. and A.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Appendix A.1. Love–Young Inequality

For any a < b , C γ ( [ a , b ] ) denotes the space of Hölder-continuous functions of order γ > 0 on [ a , b ] . Let f C λ ( [ a , b ] ) and g C μ ( [ a , b ] ) with λ + μ > 1 and
K f = sup s , t [ a , b ] s t | f ( t ) f ( s ) | | s t | λ , K g = sup s , t [ a , b ] s t | g ( t ) g ( s ) | | s t | μ .
Love–Young inequality states that for any y [ a , b ] ,
| a b f d g f ( y ) g ( b ) g ( a ) | C μ , λ K f K g ( b a ) λ + μ
with C μ , λ = ζ ( μ + λ ) , where ζ ( s ) is the Riemann zeta function, i.e., ζ ( s ) = n 1 n s ([17], p. 10).

Appendix A.2. Chain Rule

Let f = ( f 1 , , f d ) : [ a , b ] R d be a function such that for each k = 1 , , d , f k C λ ( [ a , b ] ) , λ ( 1 / 2 , 1 ] . Let g : R d R be a differentiable function with locally Lipschitz partial derivatives g k , k = 1 , , d . Then the functions g l f are Riemann–Stieltjes integrable with respect to f k , and
( g f ) ( b ) ( g f ) ( a ) = k = 1 d a b ( g k f ) d f k ,
(see [18]).

Appendix B. Several Results on fBm

Recall that fBm B H = { B t H , t 0 } with the Hurst index H ( 0 , 1 ) is a real-valued continuous centered Gaussian process with covariance
E ( B t H B s H ) = 1 2 s 2 H + t 2 H | t s | 2 H .
For H = 1 2 , fBm is a Brownian motion. To consider the strong consistency and asymptotic normality of the given estimators, we need several facts regarding B H .
Limit results (see [17,19]). Let
V n , T ( 2 ) B ^ H = n 2 H 1 T 2 H ( 4 2 2 H ) k = 1 n 1 Δ n , k ( 2 ) B H 2 , H 1 2 .
Then (see [17], pp. 46, 52, 58, 66)
V n , T ( 2 ) B ^ H n 1 a . s .
and
n V n , T ( 2 ) B ^ H 1 V 2 n , T ( 2 ) B ^ H 1 d N 0 ; Σ H , Σ H = Σ 11 Σ 12 Σ 12 Σ 22 ,
where N 0 ; Σ H is a Gaussian vector with
Σ 11 = 2 1 + 2 ( 4 2 2 H ) 2 j = 1 ϱ ^ H 2 ( j ) , Σ 22 = 1 2 Σ 11 , Σ 12 = Σ 21 = 1 2 2 H ( 4 2 2 H ) 2 j Z ϱ ˜ H 2 ( j ) , ϱ ^ H ( j ) = 1 2 6 | j | 2 H | j 2 | 2 H | j + 2 | 2 H + 4 | j 1 | 2 H + 4 | j + 1 | 2 H , ϱ ˜ H ( j ) = 1 2 | j + 1 | 2 H + 2 | j + 2 | 2 H | j + 3 | 2 H + | j 1 | 2 H 4 | j | 2 H | j 3 | 2 H + 2 | j 2 | 2 H .
Moreover,
V n , T ( 2 ) B ^ H = 1 + O ω n 1 / 2 ln 1 / 2 n
and
n ln V 2 n , T B ^ H V n , T B ^ H d N ( 0 , σ H 2 )
with σ H 2 = 3 2 Σ 11 2 Σ 12 .
Hölder-continuity of B H . It is known that almost all sample paths of an fBm B H are locally Hölder of order strictly less than H ( 0 , 1 ) . To be more precise, for all T > 0 , there exists a nonnegative random variable G γ , T such that E ( | G γ , T | p ) < for all p 1 , and
| B t H B s H | G γ , T | t s | γ a . s .
for all s , t [ 0 , T ] , where γ ( 0 , H ) (see [17], p. 4).
Sample modulus for B H . The function ϱ H ( u ) = u H | ln u | for u 0 is a sample modulus for B H , i.e., for almost all ω Ω , there is K ω < such that
| B t H ( ω ) B s H ( ω ) | K ω ϱ H ( | t s | ) f o r t , s [ 0 , T ]
(see [20], p. 48).

References

  1. Alfonsi, A. Strong order one convergence of a drift implicit Euler scheme: Application to the CIR process. Stat. Probab. Lett. 2013, 83, 602–607. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Cheng, S.R. Highly nonlinear model in finance and convergence of Monte Carlo simulations. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 2009, 353, 531–543. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Dung, N.T. Tail probabilities of solutions to a generalized Ait-Sahalia interest rate model. Stat. Probab. Lett. 2016, 112, 98–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Neuenkirch, A.; Szpruch, L. First order strong approximations of scalar SDEs defined in a domain. Numer. Math. 2014, 128, 103–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Szpruch, L.; Mao, X.; Higham, D.J.; Pan, J. Numerical simulation of a strongly nonlinear Ait-Sahalia-type interest rate model. Bit Numer. Math. 2011, 51, 405–425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Wu, F.; Mao, X.; Chen, K. A highly sensitive mean-reverting process in finance and the Euler–Maruyama approximations. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 2008, 348, 540–554. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Hu, Y.; Nualart, D.; Song, X. A singular stochastic differential equation driven by fractional Brownian motion. Stat. Probab. Lett. 2008, 78, 2075–2085. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Kubilius, K. Estimation of the Hurst index of the solutions of fractional SDE with locally Lipschitz drift. Nonlinear Anal. Model. Control 2020, 25, 1059–1078. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Lépinette, E.; Mehrdoust, F. A fractional version of the Heston model with Hurst parameter H∈(1/2,1). Dyn. Syst. Appl. 2017, 26, 535–548. [Google Scholar]
  10. Marie, N. A generalized mean-reverting equation and applications. ESAIM Probab. Stat. 2014, 18, 799–828. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Mishura, Y.; Yurchenko-Tytarenko, A. Fractional Cox–Ingersoll–Ross process with non-zero “mean”. Mod. Stoch. Theory Appl. 2018, 5, 99–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Mishura, Y.; Piterbarg, V.; Ralchenko, K.; Yurchenko-Tytarenko, A. Stochastic representation and pathwise properties of fractional Cox–Ingersoll–Ross process. Theor. Probab. Math. Statist. 2018, 97, 167–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Mishura, Y.; Yurchenko-Tytarenko, A. Fractional Cox–Ingersoll–Ross process with small Hurst indices. Mod. Stochast. Theory Appl. 2019, 6, 13–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Zhang, S.-Q.; Yuan, C. Stochastic differential equations driven by fractional Brownian motion with locally Lipschitz drift and their Euler approximation. arXiv 2018, arXiv:1812.11382. [Google Scholar]
  15. Kubilius, K.; Skorniakov, V.; Melichov, D. Estimation of parameters of SDE driven by fractional Brownian motion with polynomial drift. J. Stat. Comput. Simul. 2016, 86, 1954–1969. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Kubilius, K.; Skorniakov, V. On some estimators of the Hurst index of the solution of SDE driven by a fractional Brownian motion. Stat. Probab. Lett. 2016, 109, 159–167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Kubilius, K.; Mishura, Y.; Ralchenko, K. Parameter Estimation in Fractional Diffusion Models; Bocconi & Springer Series; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  18. Salopek, D.M. Inclusion of Fractional Brownian Motion to Model Stock Price Fluctuations. Ph.D. Thesis, Carleton University, Ottawa, ON, Canada, 1997. Available online: https://www.bac-lac.gc.ca/eng/services/theses/Pages/item.aspx?idNumber=46561235 (accessed on 23 November 2020).
  19. Kubilius, K. CLT for quadratic variation of Gaussian processes and its application to the estimation of the Orey index. Stat. Probab. Lett. 2020, 165, 108845. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Dudley, R.M.; Norvaisa, R. An Introduction to p-Variation and Young Integrals; Lecture Notes No. 1; Aarhus University: Aarhus, Denmark, 1998. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Trajectory of Y: (a) with negative values. (b) with positive values.
Figure 1. Trajectory of Y: (a) with negative values. (b) with positive values.
Mathematics 09 00018 g001
Figure 2. Probability that the trajectories have negative values: (a) Dependence of probability on Y 0 for different H. (b) Dependence of probability on Y 0 for different σ .
Figure 2. Probability that the trajectories have negative values: (a) Dependence of probability on Y 0 for different H. (b) Dependence of probability on Y 0 for different σ .
Mathematics 09 00018 g002
Figure 3. Probability that the trajectories have negative values: (a) Dependence of probability on β when H = 0.55 . (b) Dependence of probability on β when H = 0.95 .
Figure 3. Probability that the trajectories have negative values: (a) Dependence of probability on β when H = 0.55 . (b) Dependence of probability on β when H = 0.95 .
Mathematics 09 00018 g003
Figure 4. Probability that the trajectories have negative values: (a) Dependence of probability on a 1 . (b) Dependence of probability on a 2 .
Figure 4. Probability that the trajectories have negative values: (a) Dependence of probability on a 1 . (b) Dependence of probability on a 2 .
Mathematics 09 00018 g004
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kubilius, K.; Medžiūnas, A. Positive Solutions of the Fractional SDEs with Non-Lipschitz Diffusion Coefficient. Mathematics 2021, 9, 18. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/math9010018

AMA Style

Kubilius K, Medžiūnas A. Positive Solutions of the Fractional SDEs with Non-Lipschitz Diffusion Coefficient. Mathematics. 2021; 9(1):18. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/math9010018

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kubilius, Kęstutis, and Aidas Medžiūnas. 2021. "Positive Solutions of the Fractional SDEs with Non-Lipschitz Diffusion Coefficient" Mathematics 9, no. 1: 18. https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.3390/math9010018

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop